• location of the visitor¡¦s home ¡¦ how far they traveled to the site
  • how many times they visited the site in the past year or season
  • the length of the trip
  • the amount of time spent at the site
  • travel expenses
  • the person¡¦s income or other information on the value of their time
  • other socioeconomic characteristics of the visitor
  • other locations visited during the same trip, and amount of time spent at each
  • other reasons for the trip (is the trip only to visit the site, or for several purposes)
  • fishing success at the site (how many fish caught on each trip)
  • perceptions of environmental quality or quality of fishing at the site
  • substitute sites that the person might visit instead of this site
  • The value of improvements in water quality was only shown to increase the value of current beach use.  However, improved water quality can also be expected to increase overall beach use. 
  • Estimates ignore visitors from outside the Baltimore-Washington statistical metropolitan sampling area. 
  • The population and incomes in origin zones near the Chesapeake Bay beach areas are increasing,  which is likely to increase visitor-days and thus total willingness to pay.
  • changes in access costs for a recreational site
  • elimination of an existing recreational site
  • addition of a new recreational site
  • changes in environmental quality at a recreational site
  • number of visits from each origin zone (usually defined by zipcode)
  • demographic information about people from each zone
  • round-trip mileage from each zone
  • travel costs per mile
  • the value of time spent traveling, or the opportunity cost of travel time
  • exact distance that each individual traveled to the site
  • exact travel expenses
  • substitute sites that the person might visit instead of this site, and the travel distance to each
  • quality of the recreational experience at the site, and at other similar sites (e.g., fishing success)
  • perceptions of environmental quality at the site
  • characteristics of the site and other, substitute, sites
  • The travel cost method closely mimics the more conventional empirical techniques used by economists to estimate economic values based on market prices.
  • The method is based on actual behavior¡¦what people actually do¡¦rather than stated willingness to pay¡¦what people say they would do in a hypothetical situation.
  • The method is relatively inexpensive to apply.
  • On-site surveys provide opportunities for large sample sizes, as visitors tend to be interested in participating.
  • The results are relatively easy to interpret and explain.
  • The travel cost method assumes that people perceive and respond to changes in travel costs the same way that they would respond to changes in admission price.
  • The most simple models assume that individuals take a trip for a single purpose ¡¦ to visit a specific recreational site. Thus, if a trip has more than one purpose, the value of the site may be overestimated. It can be difficult to apportion the travel costs among the various purposes. 
  • Defining and measuring the opportunity cost of time, or the value of time spent traveling, can be problematic. Because the time spent traveling could have been used in other ways, it has an "opportunity cost." This should be added to the travel cost, or the value of the site will be underestimated. However, there is no strong consensus on the appropriate measure¡¦the person¡¦s wage rate, or some fraction of the wage rate¡¦and the value chosen can have a large effect on benefit estimates. In addition, if people enjoy the travel itself, then travel time becomes a benefit, not a cost, and the value of the site will be overestimated. 
  • The availability of substitute sites will affect values. For example, if two people travel the same distance, they are assumed to have the same value. However, if one person has several substitutes available but travels to this site because it is preferred, this person¡¦s value is actually higher. Some of the more complicated models account for the availability of substitutes.
  • Those who value certain sites may choose to live nearby. If this is the case, they will have low travel costs, but high values for the site that are not captured by the method.
  • Interviewing visitors on site can introduce sampling biases to the analysis.
  • Measuring recreational quality, and relating recreational quality to environmental quality can be difficult.
  • Standard travel cost approaches provides information about current conditions, but not about gains or losses from anticipated changes in resource conditions.
  • In order to estimate the demand function, there needs to be enough difference between distances traveled to affect travel costs and for differences in travel costs to affect the number of trips made. Thus, it is not well suited for sites near major population centers where many visitations may be from "origin zones" that are quite close to one another.
  • The travel cost method is limited in its scope of application because it requires user participation. It cannot be used to assign values to on-site environmental features and functions that users of the site do not find valuable. It cannot be used to value off-site values supported by the site. Most importantly, it cannot be used to measure nonuse values. Thus, sites that have unique qualities that are valued by non-users will be undervalued.
  • As in all statistical methods, certain statistical problems can affect the results. These include choice of the functional form used to estimate the demand curve, choice of the estimating method, and choice of variables included in the model.
  • GolfSW.com - Golf Southwest tips and reviews.
  • VivEcuador.com - Ecuador travel information.
  • TheChicagoTraveler.com - Explore Chicago.
  • FarmingtonValleyVisit.com - Discover Connecticut's Farmington Valley.
  • View source
  • View history
  • Community portal
  • Recent changes
  • Random page
  • Featured content
  • What links here
  • Related changes
  • Special pages
  • Printable version
  • Permanent link
  • Page information
  • Browse properties

Travel cost method

This article deals with the Travel Cost Method, which is often used in evaluating the economic value of recreational sites. This is particularly important in the coastal zone because of the level of use and the potential values that can be attached to the natural coastal and marine environment.

The Travel Cost Method (TCM) is one of the most frequently used approaches to estimating the use values of recreational sites. The TCM was initially suggested by Hotelling [1] and subsequently developed by Clawson [2] in order to estimate the benefits from recreation at natural sites. The method is based on the premise that the recreational benefits at a specific site can be derived from the demand function that relates observed users’ behaviour (i.e., the number of trips to the site) to the cost of a visit. One of the most important issues in the TCM is the choice of the costs to be taken into account. The literature usually suggests considering direct variable costs and the opportunity cost of time spent travelling to and at the site. The classical model derived from the economic theory of consumer behaviour postulates that a consumer’s choice is based on all the sacrifices made to obtain the benefits generated by a good or service. If the price ( [math]p[/math] ) is the only sacrifice made by a consumer, the demand function for a good with no substitutes is [math]x=f(p)[/math] , given income and preferences. However, the consumer often incurs other costs ( [math]c[/math] ) in addition to the out-of-pocket price, such as travel expenses, and loss of time and stress from congestion. In this case, the demand function is expressed as [math]x = f(p, c)[/math] . In other words, the price is an imperfect measure of the full cost incurred by the purchaser. Under these conditions, the utility maximising consumer’s behaviour should be reformulated in order to take such costs into account. Given two goods or services [math]x_1, x_2[/math] , their prices [math]p_1, p_2[/math] , the access costs [math]c_1, c_2[/math] and income [math]R[/math] , the utility maximising choice of the consumer is:

[math]max \, U = u(x_1,x_2) \quad subject \, to \quad (p_1+c_1)x_1+(p_2+c_2)x_2=R . \qquad (1)[/math]

Now, let [math]x_1[/math] denote the aggregate of priced goods and services, [math]x_2[/math] the number of annual visits to a recreational site, and assume for the sake of simplicity that the cost of access to the market goods is negligible ( [math]c_1 \approx 0[/math] ) and that the recreational site is free ( [math]p_2=0[/math] ). Under these assumptions, equation (1) can be written as:

[math]max \, U = u(x_1,x_2) \quad subject \, to \quad p_1x_1+c_2x_2=R . \qquad (2)[/math]

Under these conditions, the utility maximising behaviour of the consumer depends on:

The TCM is based on the assumption that changes in the costs of access to the recreational site [math]c_2[/math] have the same effect as a change in price: the number of visits to a site decreases as the cost per visit increases. Under this assumption, the demand function for visits to the recreational site is [math]x_2=f(c_2)[/math] and can be estimated using the number of annual visits as long as it is possible to observe different costs per visit. The basic TCM model is completed by the weak complementarity assumption, which states that trips are a non-decreasing function of the quality of the site, and that the individual forgoes trips to the recreational site when the quality is the lowest possible [3] , [4] . There are two basic approaches to the TCM: the Zonal approach (ZTCM) and the Individual approach (ITCM). The two approaches share the same theoretical premises, but differ from the operational point of view. The original ZTCM takes into account the visitation rate of users coming from different zones with increasing travel costs. By contrast, ITCM, developed by Brown and Nawas [5] and Gum and Martin [6] , estimates the consumer surplus by analysing the individual visitors’ behaviour and the cost sustained for the recreational activity. These are used to estimate the relationship between the number of individual visits in a given time period, usually a year, the cost per visit and other relevant socio-economic variables. The ITCM approach can be considered a refinement or a generalisation of ZTCM [7] .

Demand function.jpg

[math]x_2 = g(c_2) . \qquad (3)[/math]

The demand function can also be estimated for non-homogeneous sub-samples introducing among the independent variables income and socio-economic variables representing individual characteristics [8] . Therefore, if an individual incurs [math]c_2^e[/math] per visit, he chooses to do [math]x_2^e[/math] visits a year, while if the cost per visit increases to [math]c_2^p[/math] the number of visits will decrease to [math]x_2^p[/math] . The cost [math]cp[/math] is the choke price, that is the cost per visit that results in zero visits. The annual user surplus (the use value of the recreational site) is easily obtained by integrating the demand function from zero to the current number of annual visits, and subtracting the total expenditures on visits.

Related articles

  • ↑ Hotelling, H. (1949), Letter, In: An Economic Study of the Monetary Evaluation of Recreation in the National Parks , Washington, DC: National Park Service.
  • ↑ Clawson, M. (1959), Method for Measuring the Demand for, and Value of, Outdoor Recreation . Resources for the Future, 10, Washington, DC.
  • ↑ Freeman, A.M. III. (1993). The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory and Method , Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.
  • ↑ Herriges, J.A., C. Kling and D.J. Phaneuf (2004), 'What’s the Use? Welfare Estimates from Revealed Preference Models when Weak Complementarity Does Not Hold', Journal of Environmental Economics and Management , 47 (1), pp. 53-68.
  • ↑ Brown, W.G. and F. Nawas (1973), 'Impact of Aggregation on the Estimation of Outdoor Recreation Demand Functions', American Journal of Agricultural Economics , 55, 246-249.
  • ↑ Gum, R.L. and W.E.Martin (1974), 'Problems and Solutions in Estimating the Demand for and Value of Rural Outdoor Recreation', American Journal of Agricultural Economics , 56, 558-566.
  • ↑ Ward, F.A. and D. Beal (2000), Valuing Nature with Travel Cost Method: A Manual , Northampton: Edward Elgar.
  • ↑ Hanley, N. and C.L. Spash (1993), Cost Benefit Analysis and the Environment , Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar.
  • Definitions
  • Articles by Paolo Rosato
  • Integrated coastal zone management
  • Evaluation and assessment in coastal management
  • This page was last edited on 3 March 2022, at 21:18.
  • Privacy policy
  • About Coastal Wiki
  • Disclaimers

Powered by MediaWiki

Environmental Justice Organisations, Liabilities and Trade

Mapping environmental justice.

  • Nuclear Energy
  • Oil and Gas and Climate Justice
  • Biomass and Land Conflicts
  • Mining and Ship Breaking
  • Environmental Health and Risk Assessment
  • Liabilities and Valuation
  • Law and Institutions
  • Consumption, Ecologically Unequal Exchange and Ecological Debt

Travel-cost method

The travel-cost method (TCM) is used for calculating economic values of environmental goods. Unlike the contingent valuation method, TCM can only estimate use value of an environmental good or service. It is mainly applied for determining economic values of sites that are used for recreation, such as national parks. For example, TCM can estimate part of economic benefits of coral reefs, beaches or wetlands stemming from their use for recreational activities (diving and snorkelling/swimming and sunbathing/bird watching). It can also serve for evaluating how an increased entrance fee a nature park would affect the number of visitors and total park revenues from the fee. However, it cannot estimate benefits of providing habitat for endemic species.

TCM is based on the assumption that travel costs represent the price of access to a recreational site. Peoples’ willingness to pay for visiting a site is thus estimated based on the number of trips that they make at different travel costs. This is called a revealed preference technique, because it ‘reveals’ willingness to pay based on consumption behaviour of visitors.

The information is collected by conducting a survey among the visitors of a site being valued. The survey should include questions on the number of visits made to the site over some period (usually during the last 12 months), distance travelled from visitor’s home to the site, mode of travel (car, plane, bus, train, etc.), time spent travelling to the site, respondents’ income, and other socio-economic characteristics (gender, age, degree of education, etc). The researcher uses the information on distance and mode of travel to calculate travel costs. Alternatively, visitors can be asked directly in a survey to state their travel costs, although this information tends to be somewhat less reliable. Time spent travelling is considered as part of the travel costs, because this time has an opportunity cost. It could have been used for doing other activities (e.g. working, spending time with friends or enjoying a hobby). The value of time is determined based on the income of each respondent. Time spent at the site is for the same reason also considered as part of travel costs. For example, if respondents visit three different sites in 10 days and spend only 1 day at the site being valued, then only fraction of their travel costs should be assigned to this site (e.g. 1/10). Depending on the fraction used, the final benefit estimates can differ considerably.

Two approaches of TCM are distinguished – individual and zonal. Individual TCM calculates travel costs separately for each individual and requires a more detailed survey of visitors. In zonal TCM, the area surrounding the site is divided into zones, which can be either concentric circles or administrative districts. In this case, the number of visits from each zone is counted. This information is sometimes available (e.g. from the site management), which makes data collection from the visitors simpler and less expensive.

The relationship between travel costs and number of trips (the higher the travel costs, the fewer trips visitors will take) shows us the demand function for the average visitor to the site, from which one can derive the average visitor’s willingness to pay. This average value is then multiplied by the total relevant population in order to estimate the total economic value of a recreational resource.

TCM is based on the behaviour of people who actually use an environmental good and therefore cannot measure non-use values. This method is thus inappropriate for sites with unique characteristics which have a large non-use economic value component (because many people would be willing to pay for its preservation just to know that it exists, although they do not plan to visit the site in the future).

The travel-cost method might also be combined with contingent valuation to estimate an economic value of a change (either enhancement or deterioration) in environmental quality of the NP by asking the same tourists how many trips they would make in the case of a certain quality change. This information could help in estimating the effects that a particular policy causing an environmental quality change would have on the number of visitors and on the economic use value of the NP.

For further reading:

Ward, F.A., Beal, D. (2000) Valuing nature with travel cost models. A manual. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.

Ecosystem valuation [ www.ecosystemvaluation.org/travel_costs.htm ]

This glossary entry is based on a contribution by Ivana Logar 

EJOLT glossary editors:   Hali Healy, Sylvia Lorek and Beatriz Rodríguez-Labajos

One comment

I quite like reading a post that will make people think. Also, thanks for allowing me to comment!

Browse by Theme

Browse by type.

  • Presentations
  • Press Releases
  • Scientific Papers

Online course

Online course on ecological economics: http://www.ejolt.org/2013/10/online-course-ecological-economics-and-activism/

Privacy Policy | Credits

U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

Here's how you know

Official websites use .gov A .gov website belongs to an official government organization in the United States.

Secure .gov websites use HTTPS A lock ( ) or https:// means you’ve safely connected to the .gov website. Share sensitive information only on official, secure websites.

Home

  •   Facebook
  •   Twitter
  •   Linkedin
  •   Digg
  •   Reddit
  •   Pinterest
  •   Email

Latest Earthquakes |    Chat Share Social Media  

The travel cost method and the economic value of leisure time

Recent estimates of high values for tourist related recreation USA amenity values indicate that allocation of basic water and terrestrial resources to recreation activities should be given precedence over conventional market oriented activities that often degrade or even extirpate the resource. We discuss at length the travel cost method (TCM), a survey based technique that quantifies the non-market benefits of trips to recreation sites. The TCM has been cast in the role of an ‘umpire’ in recent resource allocation debates. Understanding the key role of the TCM in the debate will aid tourist agency officials throughout the world. This article is a U.S. Government work and is in the public domain in the U.S.A.

Citation Information

how travel cost method works

Travel Cost Method (TCM)

Some amenities do not have a direct cost associated with them. For example, recreational sites may be free to enter. In order to apply a value to these types of amenities a value is often derived from a good or service which is complementary to the consumption of the free amenity. One method of estimating a value is therefore to collect data on the travel costs associated with accessing the amenity or recreational site. This is commonly referred to as the travel cost method of estimating the value of an amenity.

The travel cost method involves collecting data on the costs incurred by each individual in travelling to the recreational site or amenity. This ‘price’ paid by visitors is unique to each individual, and is calculated by summing the travel costs from each individuals original location to the amenity. By aggregating the observed travel costs associated with a number of individuals accessing the amenity a demand curve can be estimated, and as such a price can be obtained for the non-price amenity.

We can show this method of using observed or revealed preferences using a diagram as shown below.

TCM

D(Visits) shows the overall trend between travel costs and visit rates at a particular asset or site. To generate an estimate of the recreational value for the site, estimates are needed for the average visitors (V1) total recreational value for the site. This is then multiplied by the total number of visitors per annum giving the total annual recreational value of the site or asset. For a more complete explanation continue to the flash example .

Zonal Travel Cost Method Example

Using the zonal travel cost method a researcher can estimate the value of an asset by exploring the actual visitors or users of a site or asset, rather than potential visitors or users. The level of analysis focuses on the zones in which people live compared to the location of the asset. The researcher is required to specify the zones from which the site users travel to the asset.

Consider an example of valuing a country park. In this example four zones have been designated by the researcher. Zone A has an average travel time of 1 hour, and a distance of 25km. Zone B has an average travel time of 1.5 hours and a distance of 40km. Zone C has an average travel time of approximately 2 hours and a distance of 80km. Finally, zone D has an average travel time of 4 hours and a distance of 120km. The admission cost for all users is the same, and is equal to £10. The number of visits per year has been observed by the researcher for each zone. Zone A has an average of 10,000 visits per year. Zone B has an average of 12,000 visits per year, zone C has 8,000 visits, and zone D has 4,000 visits. This information is shown in the table below.

To calculate the value of the asset (V) for a single visit the researcher now uses the simple equation as follows:

V = ((T x w ) + (D x v ) + Ca) x Va

T = travel time (in hours) w = average wage rate (£/hour) D = distance (in km) v = marginal vehicle operating costs Ca = cost of Admission to asset Va = average number of visits per year

Using the country park example, the value of the asset can be calculated using this formula. It is important that the researcher provides an accurate measure for the average hourly wage rate, and also for the marginal vehicle operating costs. A common value for the operating costs is around £0.16p per km. This is the equivalent of around £0.40p per mile, a standard value given for vehicle operating costs in calculating expenses claims within firms and organisations.

In the example the average hourly wage rate is £10, and marginal vehicle operating costs are calculated at £0.16p per km. The researcher can now calculate the value of the country park for each zone to get an overall value for the asset. This is shown in the table below.

Limitations of the TCM

There are a number of limitations associated with the travel cost method of value estimation. These are as follows:

(1) Difficulties in measuring the cost of visiting a site.

It may actually be quite difficult to measure the cost of accessing a site or amenity. This is because of the opportunity cost associated with the travel time. If the opportunity cost of all individuals is the same then the estimated price will be accurate. If, however, the opportunity cost of individuals accessing the site varies, which is more likely, then the measure will be inaccurate.

For example, one individual’s opportunity cost of the travel time spent accessing a recreational site is equivalent to one hours wage equalling £35. However, another individual’s opportunity cost for an hours wage is only £8. This is problematic to the TCM as if individual’s opportunity costs differ including the costs of time spent at the site, this would change the price faced by different individuals by different amounts.

(2) The estimation of willingness to pay used in the TCM is for entire site access rather than specific features.

As the TCM only provides a price or value relating to the cost of accessing the amenity or recreational site, it does so for the whole site. It may, however, be the case that we wish to value a certain aspect of the site in our project appraisal. For example, we do not wish to value a whole park, but instead the fishing ponds within it.

(3) The exclusion of the marginal cost of other complementary goods.

The travel cost method does not account for the costs involved in purchasing complementary goods which may be required in order to enjoy accessing the amenity. For example, individuals accessing a park area may take a football with them, or a picnic. Alternatively, individuals accessing a recreational site may take walking equipment and tents with them. The marginal costs of using this equipment should be included in the price estimated.

(4) Multi-purpose or multi-activity journeys.

Individuals may visit an amenity or recreational site in the morning, but then visit another site or enjoy some other activity in the afternoon. The travel endured to access the amenity was also undertaken to enable access to the afternoon activity. In this case the cost incurred in travelling to the amenity does not represent the value the individuals place on the amenity, but that which they place on both the amenity they visited in the morning and the one which they visited in the afternoon.

(5) Journey value.

It may be the case that the journey itself has a value to the individual. If this is true then some of the cost incurred in travelling to the amenity should not actually be applied to the individual accessing the amenity, and as such should be removed from the estimation of the amenities value.

(6) Assumed responses to changes in price.

The TCM method assumes that individuals respond to changes in price regardless of its composition. For example, TCM assumes that individuals will react consistently to a £10 increase in travel cost as they would to a £10 increase in admission costs.

Search CBA Builder:

  • What is CBA?
  • Costs/Benefits
  • Environ. Assess.
  • Impact Assess.
  • Quantification
  • Shadow Pricing
  • Revealed Pref.
  • Hedonic Pricing
  • Life and Injury
  • Discounting
  • Discount/Compound
  • Horizon Values
  • Sensitivity Analysis
  • Comparing NPV and BCR
  • CBA Builder
  • Worksheets/Exercises
  • 1: Discounting
  • 2: Multi-year Discounting
  • 3: Multi-year Discounting
  • 4: Shadow Pricing
  • 5: NPV and BCR
  • 6: CBA Builder
  • Useful Texts
  • Journals: Concept.
  • Journals: Applic.

how travel cost method works

Quick Links

how travel cost method works

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0 Unported License .

Creative Commons License

This resource was created by Dr Dan Wheatley. The project was funded by the Economics Network and the Centre for Education in the Built Environment (CEBE) as part of the Teaching and Learning Development Projects 2010/11.

Goodbye Genie+? Big changes are coming to Disney World’s ride reservation system

how travel cost method works

  • Disney Genie+ is going away at Walt Disney World, sort of.
  • Starting July 24, Genie+ will be called Lightning Lane Multi Pass, and Individual Lightning Lanes will be called Lightning Lane Single Passes.
  • Guests will be able to reserve rides and shows ahead of time instead of having to wait for park days.

Disney Genie+ is going away at Walt Disney World , sort of.

Starting July 24, Genie+ will be called Lightning Lane Multi Pass, and Individual Lightning Lanes will be called Lightning Lane Single Passes, but that’s not the biggest change. 

Beginning that same day, guests will be able to reserve rides and shows ahead of time instead of having to wait for park days, as part of changes first teased in May 2023 .

“Lightning Lane passes will blend features from our current services and the previously offered FastPass+ service, giving guests the choice to plan ahead and removing the hassle of planning during their vacation,”  the Florida resort announced Tuesday .

Here’s what guests should know.

How does Disney Lightning Lane work?

The Lightning Lane Multi Pass will include the same rides currently covered by Genie+ as well as Tiana’s Bayou Adventure , which opens on June 28. A la carte Lightning Lane Single Passes will be available for the most popular attractions at each park, like Individual Lightning Lanes .

However, starting July 24, guests will no longer have to wait for their park day to reserve experiences. 

  • Guests staying at Disney World’s resort hotels can make selections up to seven days in advance, all at once, for up to 14 days of their stay. Other guests can make selections up to three days in advance.
  • Guests can make up to three advance Lightning Lane Multi Pass selections for each day of their trip. Once they arrive at the park and complete their first experience, they can book additional experiences pending availability. Lightning Lane Single Passes remain limited to two per day, like Individual Lightning Lanes are currently.
  • Guests will also be able to see prices and select attraction times before purchasing passes “​​so you know what you’re getting.” Currently, guests have to purchase Genie+ before they can see availability. Disney World’s app and website will be updated for easier planning and purchasing.

How much is the Lightning Lane at Disney World?

Disney Lightning Lane pricing varies by date and park. 

There will be no price increase related to these changes.

Halfway to the holidays: Disney announces the return of Jollywood Nights

Why is Genie+ changing?

Disney World said: “Guests have told us they would prefer to have the option to do more of their planning before their theme park day. So, this summer we will make changes to our Disney Genie+ service and individual Lightning Lane entry, including new ways to plan ahead.”

Will Disney Genie still be available?

The free Disney Genie planning tool will still be available for all guests to help plan their trips. The paid Genie+ service is the one changing.

Is Disneyland’s Genie+ changing?

Disneyland will also adopt the new names for Disney Genie+ and Individual Lightning Lanes, but they will still operate the way they do currently.

The Key Points at the top of this article were created with the assistance of Artificial Intelligence (AI) and reviewed by a journalist before publication. No other parts of the article were generated using AI. Learn more .

2023-24 Working from home deductions

On this page, fixed rate method, actual cost method, occupancy expenses, keeping good records.

Person working on laptop at home

Have you been working from the comfort of home? You may be able to claim a tax deduction for your working from home expenses. To be eligible, you need to:

incur extra running costs related to working from home

be doing work-related tasks from home, not just minor tasks (like checking emails)

have records to prove your expenses.

You can claim a fixed rate of 67 cents for each hour you work from home. This rate covers:

energy costs – for heating, cooling and lighting

phone and data usage expenses – for your home phone, mobile and internet services

computer consumables and stationery costs – for office supplies like printer ink.

If you’ve bought office equipment like a desk or monitor, you can separately claim an immediate deduction for each item that cost $300 or under . Looking to claim a deduction for an item that cost more than $300 ? See our info about depreciating assets you use for work  this opens in a new window  .

Check out how to calculate your deductions using the fixed rate method  this opens in a new window  on our website.

Use the actual cost method to claim the actual work-related portion of the extra expenses you’ve incurred when working from home. This method involves detailed calculations and keeping good records.

Examples and tools to help you work out your deductions using the actual cost method  this opens in a new window  are available on our website.

As an employee you generally won’t be eligible to claim your occupancy expenses (like a portion of your rent, insurance, or mortgage interest). Instead, you can claim the extra running expenses  this opens in a new window  you incur when working from home.

You can check your eligibility to claim occupancy expenses  this opens in a new window  on our website.

Keep in mind if you claim occupancy expenses there are capital gains tax  this opens in a new window  (CGT) implications for your home.

Remember to keep track of your work-related expenses.

If you’re claiming your working from home running expenses using the fixed rate method , you must keep:

a record of the total number of hours you work from home during the income year. You must keep this record at the time you work the hours, an estimate won’t be accepted

at least one record for each expense you incur that the rate per hour includes. For example, one electricity bill.

For the actual cost method , you need to keep:

a record your total hours worked from home during the income year. Or a record over a continuous 4-week period showing your usual working from home pattern

receipts and bills for all your expenses

information and records showing how you worked out your deductions.

The myDeductions  this opens in a new window  tool in the ATO app is a handy way to keep track of your work-related expenses (and other deductions).

For more info on how to claim your work from home expenses  this opens in a new window  , visit our website.

Related articles

Where's my tax return.

27 Sept 2021 · 4 min read time

How much tax should I pay on a second job? Claiming the tax-free threshold

27 Sept 2021 · 3 min read time

Spouse details and your tax return

27 Sept 2021 · 2 min read time

Top liked users

Avatar of platypus

Top contributors

7077 contributions

1270 contributions

1089 contributions

656 contributions

how travel cost method works

Anonymous1283

452 contributions

How to upgrade to first class without spending a ton of money

Christina Ly

Editor's Note

For many travelers, flying in a first-class seat may seem like an unachievable dream reserved for the ultra-wealthy or business travelers who spare no expense. But in reality, there are many other ways to score a seat at the front of the plane without paying an exorbitant amount.

In many cases, there are even ways to upgrade to first class (or business class) without having elite status in an airline's frequent flyer program or paying the full cash or award retail price.

Admittedly, in these days of high travel demand , it's hard to guarantee a first-class seat without directly paying for it. However, with some luck, tips and strategy, there are options out there.

How to upgrade to first class without elite status

how travel cost method works

One of the easiest ways to score a first-class upgrade is to have elite status. Many airlines offer complimentary upgrades as a loyalty perk.

However, it's possible to snag an upgrade without paying full price, even if you don't have status.

Here are some strategies to consider.

Use miles to upgrade your economy ticket

One of the easiest ways for travelers without elite status to upgrade their seats to first or business class without paying the full cash price is by paying for the upgrade with miles .

This won't require elite status, but it does require you to have a decent stash of frequent flyer miles with an airline or credit card rewards points you've earned through your everyday spending.

Even casual flyers might be surprised at how many points and miles they can earn by charging their daily expenses to the right credit card; many of these points and miles can be transferred to airline frequent flyer programs and redeemed for travel, including upgrades.

For example, American Airlines will allow American AAdvantage members to use miles to upgrade tickets. You'll generally pay some miles and a fee for an upgrade.

Related: Best airline credit cards

how travel cost method works

As you might expect, upgrading to first class on a short domestic flight is much less pricey than moving to a lie-flat business-class seat on an overseas flight. The latter costs 25,000 miles plus $350 per traveler for upgrades to business class from standard economy seats.

how travel cost method works

You'll want to consider your miles' value before making the splurge. Per TPG's June 2024 valuations , 25,000 AAdvantage miles are worth $425. But remember, in this scenario, you'll need to also pay $350 in addition to redeeming miles.

That said, if you prioritize having a comfortable seat to sleep in during your overnight flight to Europe, using your miles for an upgrade can be a far better option than paying for a business-class ticket outright.

For example, a round-trip economy ticket from New York to Rome costs $1,171 versus $6,564 for a Flagship business-class seat.

how travel cost method works

An award ticket on the same round-trip itinerary costs a whopping 592,000 miles for business class.

how travel cost method works

Not many people have more than $6,500 to spend on one flight to Europe, and 592,000 miles is a hefty price to pay.

On the other hand, after purchasing an economy ticket, you may be able to upgrade it for 25,000 miles plus $350, one-way, if available. Regardless of the airline, before you wade too deeply into upgrade pricing, make sure the ticket you purchased is eligible for upgrades. On many airlines, restrictive basic economy tickets are not eligible for changes, including upgrades.

If you don't have 25,000 AAdvantage miles at the ready, a credit card welcome bonus could help get you there. Right now, the Citi® / AAdvantage® Executive World Elite Mastercard® (see rates and fees ) is offering new members an impressive 100,000 bonus miles for cardholders who spend $10,000 in their first three months with the card. The card carries a $595 annual fee but includes sizeable perks like an Admirals Club membership and a Global Entry or TSA PreCheck application statement fee credit.

Related: The best ways to travel to Europe using points and miles

Upgrade through your credit card travel portal

There are credit card rewards programs that will help members upgrade their flights. Some American Express cardholders can use their American Express Membership Rewards points (or pay) to upgrade a flight on an airline with which Amex partners.

To look into an upgrade, you'll need to make the request through your Amex Travel account.

how travel cost method works

Airlines that partner with Amex include Air Canada (Star Alliance), Qantas (Oneworld), Aeromexico (SkyTeam) and Etihad, among others.

Get help from a friend or family member with elite status

You can still receive some airline elite perks without personally having elite status. Some airline programs like Alaska Airlines Mileage Plan will allow their members to spread the wealth of their elite status to family and friends.

Those with Alaska MVP Gold status or higher receive four one-way guest upgrades for every year they gain or maintain their status. They can spend the upgrades on their travel companions or when their guest travels without them.

There are some rules around space availability and other factors to consider. Still, if your friend or a family member has status with an airline such as Alaska Airlines or United Airlines, they may be able to help you get upgraded without spending any money.

how travel cost method works

Bid for an upgrade

Even if you don't have any miles saved up or have never been a frequent flyer, you may still be able to fly in first class without breaking the bank.

Some airlines will send out an invitation to bid for an upgrade if they expect some empty premium seats on a flight. These invitation texts or emails allow you to bid for a seat in the next available cabin. If you have some miles stashed, some airlines, like Australian carrier Qantas, will also allow you to submit a bid composed of miles and cash.

how travel cost method works

Not all routes are eligible for upgrades, and other restrictions may apply. Rules will vary by airline, but most will have a suggested bid and a minimum amount you'll need to offer. Keep in mind that many airlines restrict you to bidding for one class of an upgrade, so you may need to be booked in premium economy (if it's available on your flight) in order to score a business-class seat via a winning bid.

Buy a discounted upgrade

The cash price to upgrade to first class can decrease if the airline doesn't expect to sell all seats at the full fare. Many airlines would rather get some revenue for the seat than none at all.

If you notice low demand for your desired seat as the travel date approaches, see if you can scoop up an upgrade at a discounted cash rate.

While the price will vary, it never hurts to check. Look at your upcoming flight reservations every now to see what the airline is listing as the cost to upgrade your seat with cash.

Ask about first-class upgrades at the check-in counter

Unfortunately, the price for a first-class seat often doesn't drop. However, it never hurts to ask about a last-minute upgrade.

Airlines make more money from filling their first-class seats, so next time you're feeling a little spendy, you can ask at the ticket or boarding counter if there is any availability at the front of the plane. You may even find the extra cost is lower than expected, especially when factoring in any fees you'd otherwise have to pay for add-ons like checked bags.

How to upgrade to first class with elite status

how travel cost method works

Unsurprisingly, getting upgraded to first class with elite status is much easier. Many airlines offer complimentary upgrades as a perk of elite status. The exact process differs from one airline to the next, but often, the higher-tier status you have, the more luck you'll have.

That means that unless you're a higher-level elite member, you may be low on the waiting list for an upgrade.

However, you can try additional tricks to position yourself in a premium seat.

Purchase instant First Class Upgrade tickets with Alaska Airlines

While many airlines will upgrade elite status members one, two or a few days before departure, Alaska Airlines Mileage Plan's elite members can buy certain fares that qualify them for an immediate upgrade.

When booking a trip like the one pictured below, you will see four fare options instead of the typical two Main and first-class fares after checking your elite status in the fare type column to the left.

how travel cost method works

The Premium Class Upgrade option is for an extra legroom seat, whereas the First Class Upgrade option is for the airline's first-class cabin.

By purchasing an upgrade fare, you'll be eligible — pending availability — for an immediate upgrade instead of waiting until the days before your flight for your upgrade to clear.

How do you know if there's availability? Look for the "F" symbols by the flight details. A navy blue "F" square means there is availability on that particular flight; a white "F" square means there isn't.

You'll be placed on the upgrade waitlist if you don't buy an immediate upgrade-eligible fare.

Use your upgrade certificates with Delta Air Lines

Delta SkyMiles , Delta Air Lines' frequent flyer program, features four published Delta Medallion elite tiers : Silver, Gold, Platinum and Diamond Medallion. All come with perks, including the chance to receive complimentary upgrades to first-class seats.

Access to unlimited, free upgrades to first class comes standard with Delta Medallion elite status, but Delta's upgrade process is still complex. You can increase your chances of being upgraded on Delta by being a higher-tier Platinum or Diamond Medallion member.

Members in these two elite tiers receive upgrade certificates known as Global Upgrade Certificates and Regional Upgrade Certificates. If upgrade space is available, these certificates can be cleared as soon as you book your ticket.

Like many airlines, Delta has certain fares that are not eligible for complimentary upgrades through Medallion status.

Use PlusPoints for priority upgrades with United Airlines

United has a complicated revenue, award and upgrade class system that can be confusing for even experienced flyers.

Luckily, TPG has made it easier to understand United's system with this comprehensive guide to United fare classes .

All United MileagePlus Premier members are eligible for complimentary Premier upgrades on eligible fares and routes, but only Premier Platinum and Premier 1K members receive PlusPoints .

Using PlusPoints, high-tier Premier members can confirm their upgrades long before their flight. Premier Platinum members receive 40 PlusPoints when reaching status, and Premier 1K members receive 280 PlusPoints when they earn or retain their status.

The screenshot below shows United's PlusPoints pricing breakdown for upgrades. For instance, it takes 40 PlusPoints to move from economy to Polaris business class on a long-haul flight.

how travel cost method works

Generally, you should reserve PlusPoints for long-haul Polaris flights to get the best value for your points. However, sitting up front is always better than in the back, regardless of the route. This is especially true if you have points set to expire soon, as it's best to use them for any first-class option rather than let them go to waste.

how travel cost method works

Instead, whether you are on a business-class cash fare or a redemption, look out for upgrade offers in your inbox before the flight during online check-in, or ask at the check-in desk at the airport.

While the upgrade cost is likely four figures, it could be worth it to experience some of the best products in commercial aviation.

Related: Swiss first class review: Is it worth paying $1,000 to $2,000 to upgrade?

Bottom line

Whether you want to treat yourself once or increase the number of times you sit up front, getting upgraded to first class is possible and feasible.

From cashing in miles for an upgrade to winning the upgrade lottery with a cash bid, there are several ways to snag an upgraded seat without spending much money, including with elite status or the right credit card. Even those without elite status can score a prime seat in the front of the plane with careful planning.

  • Search Please fill out this field.
  • Manage Your Subscription
  • Give a Gift Subscription
  • Newsletters
  • Sweepstakes
  • Travel Tips

The Best Time to Book a Flight for Domestic, International, and Summer Travel

Here are our best tips for booking travel in 2024.

how travel cost method works

When to Book Flights for Domestic Travel

When to book flights for international travel, when to book flights for summer 2024 travel, when to book flights for holiday 2024 travel.

Buying plane tickets is something of an art form. Ideally, you want to secure your spot months in advance to avoid the inevitable price spike as your travel dates get closer. But sometimes the best time to book a flight also depends on the destination and whether it's domestic or abroad. The trends are always changing, but experts say the sweet spot for booking domestic flights is 28 days, or 60 days for international flights.

Flights generally open for booking about a year ahead of time, and the airfare will change often between then and takeoff. Although you can book just a couple of weeks before the departure date in some cases, prices are likely to be astronomical. In other cases, when you want to go somewhere popular or during a big travel weekend, flights could fill up faster than normal. Our advice: Track flight prices on Google Flights or Hopper as early as possible so you can keep an eye on cost fluctuations. Read on for more advice about when to book flights from the pros.

According to Expedia's 2024 Air Travel Hacks report , you should aim to book 28 days before your domestic flight. "Doing so can save travelers up to 24 percent compared to those who wait until the last minute, from zero to six days out," Expedia travel expert Christie Hudson tells Travel + Leisure.

For domestic trips, pricing is elevated when tickets are first released, about a year before the flight. Those prices will slowly creep downward, all the way to their lowest point in the prime booking window, after which you'll likely see a huge increase in cost for last-minute travel.

Meet the Expert

Christie Hudson is a travel expert at top booking site Expedia.

You're better off booking earlier rather than later for international travel, but the Expedia report says ideally no more than four months before your desired departure date. The sweet spot is around 60 days. "This is a big change from 2022 data, which showed the cheapest fares were secured when travelers booked four to six months out." Hudson says. "2023 data revealed that people who booked that far in advance actually paid more on average." The report says the least expensive day of the week to book is Sunday and the most expensive is Friday, for both domestic and international travel.

But there is some regional variance. Going , a platform that tracks flight prices and notifies members of good deals, has found the best months to book flights to Africa, Asia, Oceania, Europe, and Latin America, for travel about 60 days out. Here's what it says.

Africa: Book in May.

Asia: Book in August or October, followed by April or September.

Oceania: Book in November, January, or July.

Europe: Book in August, October, or November.

Latin America: Book in October.

The real trick to finding good deals on international airfare is to avoid booking your travel for peak times, which include summer and major holidays (don't forget — that includes holidays in your destination, too).

Summer is traditionally one of the most popular times of the year to travel, which means it can be tough to find a good deal on airfare. Ideally, you should book flights for summer travel as soon as possible, preferably at least six months in advance.

"The best time to book for peak season is … the opposite season," says Katy Nastro, travel expert at Going. "While most of us are scrambling to focus on our winter holiday plans, we should also keep our eyes open for some great summer fares."

She notes that the booking window for peak season ranges between three and seven months for domestic flights and four to 10 months for international trips. "And if you do book something, keep that flight alert on," says Nastro. "If it drops again, depending on your ticket type, you can call to rebook and get a refund or travel credit back with the difference."

Katy Nastro is a travel expert at Going, a website that finds flight deals to more than 900 destinations around the world.

Around the winter holidays is the priciest time to travel, Nastro says. "Your best bet is to remember the Goldilocks zones: look to book between three to seven months ahead for domestic travel and four to 10 months ahead for international travel."

Hudson advises that at the very latest, your holiday travel should be booked by mid-October. "But the biggest holiday travel savings actually come from choosing the right dates," she says. "Avoiding the busiest days like the Wednesday before Thanksgiving and the Friday and Saturday before Christmas will yield major savings."

Track flights and book your holiday tickets as soon as you find a decent deal, but make sure to book a fare that will give you a credit if you cancel (generally speaking, that means don't book basic economy). That way, if prices drop between the time of booking and your travel dates, you can cancel your original ticket and use the credit to book the cheaper fare. The only downside is you'll still have some remaining credit, but you can then use it to treat yourself to a future flight. Just don't let that credit expire.

Related Articles

Advertisement

Advertisement

The Individual Travel Cost Method with Consumer-Specific Values of Travel Time Savings

  • Open access
  • Published: 24 June 2019
  • Volume 74 , pages 961–984, ( 2019 )

Cite this article

You have full access to this open access article

how travel cost method works

  • Mikołaj Czajkowski   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0001-5118-2308 1 ,
  • Marek Giergiczny 1 ,
  • Jakub Kronenberg 2 &
  • Jeffrey Englin 3  

11k Accesses

27 Citations

Explore all metrics

The treatment of the opportunity cost of travel time in travel cost models has been an area of research interest for many decades. Our analysis develops a methodology to combine the travel distance and travel time data with respondent-specific estimates of the value of travel time savings (VTTS). The individual VTTS are elicited with the use of discrete choice stated preference methods. The travel time valuation procedure is integrated into the travel cost valuation exercise to create a two-equation structural model of site valuation. Since the travel time equation of the structural model incorporates individual preference heterogeneity, the full structure model provides a travel cost site demand model based upon individualized values of time. The methodology is illustrated in a study of recreational birdwatching, more specifically, visits to a ‘stork village’ in Poland. We show that the usual practice of basing respondents’ VTTS on 1/3 of their wage rate is largely unfounded and propose alternatives—including a separate component of the travel cost survey aimed at valuation of respondents’ VTTS or, as a second best, asking if they wish if their journey was shorter and for those who do—use full hourly wage as an indicator of their VTTS.

Similar content being viewed by others

how travel cost method works

Impact of tourism development upon environmental sustainability: a suggested framework for sustainable ecotourism

how travel cost method works

A typology of U.S. metropolises by rent burden and its major drivers

how travel cost method works

Rural–nonrural divide in car access and unmet travel need in the United States

Avoid common mistakes on your manuscript.

1 Introduction

This analysis proposes a structural model of the travel cost demand approach (TCM) that includes two components. One component is used to estimate the value of travel time for each individual in the sample. The second component incorporates that value of travel time into the travel cost variable that is used in the estimation of the site demand. While the travel cost demand curve is estimated using the widely applied count methodology, the travel time component of the model is based on a discrete choice stated preference method. Our approach avoids arbitrary assumptions about an individual’s value of time in an appealing way. It also allows quite intricate valuations since the stated preference portion of the model can accommodate a wide range of travel modes, time constraints, family situations and other considerations that can affect the value of one’s time when traveling for recreation.

The individual level approach to valuing travel time utilized in this analysis is made possible by relatively recent advances in modeling preference heterogeneity in stated preference studies. The advances allow the derivation of posterior estimates of each individual’s taste parameters . We argue that utilizing individual-specific values of travel time savings, based on respondents’ stated preferences, provides a feasible method for empirically incorporating the value of travel time into travel cost demand studies. Through an empirical illustration we show that the proposed approach is tractable. All it requires is the inclusion of only a few discrete choice experiment (DCE) questions in a TCM survey and a proper econometric treatment.

Our results show that using arbitrary assumptions concerning individuals’ value of travel time savings (VTTS) equal to a given share of their wage rate (e.g., 1/3) are largely unfounded. First of all, nearly half of respondents say they do not wish their journey to the site was shorter, indicating positive utility of leisure travel. Those who wished to shorten the journey were willing to pay amounts which appear only mildly correlated with their estimated wage rates. Overall, the average consumer surplus per trip calculated from the model with individual-specific VTTS were the closest to the model which used respondents’ full wage rate included for respondents who said they wish their journey was shorter (and zero for others). We suggest using this approach as the second best, in the case eliciting individual specific VTTS was not possible.

1.1 Economics of Time: What Do We Know

In 1965 Becker postulated that “time can be converted into money”. The basic idea is that people choose how much labor to supply, given a constraint that total time available is divided among work, leisure, and travel. At its bare bones, this model implies that travel time is valued at the after-tax wage rate. This is because the Becker model assumes that time can be transferred freely between work and leisure, so any marginal savings in travel time can be used to increase labor income. This model has been expanded in many directions. A common starting point is DeSerpa ( 1971 ). This model assumes that utility is affected by commodity bundles \(X = (X_{1} , \ldots ,X_{n} ,T_{1} , \ldots ,T_{n} )\) where \(X_{i}\) denotes some quantity of the i -th good, while \(T_{i}\) denotes the amount of time allocated to the i -th good. These goods can include both travel to a recreational site and time onsite. \(T_{w}\) denotes time spent at work (which may increase or decrease utility). Each activity has a minimum time requirement \(\bar{T}\) (hence constraint \(T_{i} \ge \bar{T}\) ). There is also an overall time constraint \(T_{w} + \sum {T_{i} } \le T^{0}\) . The budget constraint is \(P_{i} X_{i} \le Y + wT_{w}\) , where \(Y\) is unearned income. As a result, the problem can be stated as:

This problem can be solved by formulating a Lagrangian function, in which each constraint is associated with a Lagrange multiplier indicating how tight it is (i.e., the rate at which utility could be increased by relaxing it a little). Let \(\lambda\) , \(\mu\) , and \(\kappa\) be the Lagrangian multipliers for the budget constraint, the overall time constraint, and the activity-specific time constraints, respectively. The solution to the optimization problem yields:

Equation ( 2 ) states that value of time as a personal resource (or simply value of leisure) equals wage rate plus the value of utility from work. If \(T_{i}\) in Eq. ( 3 ) is not restricted to its minimum then by the virtue of complementary slackness condition its multiplier would be zero. Which in turn implies that VTTS = 0 and that \(\frac{{\partial U/\partial T_{i} }}{\lambda } = w + \frac{{\partial U/\partial T_{w} }}{\lambda }\) , that is, the value of marginal utility from the activity \(i\) would be equal to value of leisure. In other words, if a person spends on an activity more time than the minimum required (the constraint \(\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} {\kappa_{i} } (T_{i} - \bar{T}) \ge 0\) is not binding), such activity would be what DeSerpa ( 1971 ) calls a pure leisure good and its value equals to the value of time as a resource. On the other hand, if \(\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} {\kappa_{i} } (T_{i} - \bar{T}) = 0\) then \({{\kappa_{i} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\kappa_{i} } \lambda }} \right. \kern-0pt} \lambda }\) can be interpreted as value of time saved (VTTS) in the activity \(i\) .

Most work in the transportation field assumes traveling is a means to an end and travel time is a disutility to be minimized. However, in the recent years new concepts emerged, including the so-called positive utility of travel, which suggests that travel can provide benefits and may be motivated by factors beyond reaching activity destinations (see, e.g., Mokhtarian and Salomon 2001 ; Mokhtarian 2005 ). Positive utility of travel implies that \(\partial U/\partial T_{i}\) is positive. In the extreme case, if positive utility of time offsets \(w + \frac{{\partial U/\partial T_{w} }}{\lambda }\) then VTTS would be zero. However, note that VTTS = 0 does not mean that the value of time is zero.

Time is scarce and the time spent on traveling to the site as well as the time spent on the site is time that could have been devoted to other activities. The value of those lost opportunities is the time cost of the trip. It is important to distinguish between VTTS and the value of time in terms of lost opportunities. If the main goal of the analysis was to estimate benefits from a new road or any other public investment that would result in time savings then the analysis should focus on monetizing benefits from time saved. However, if the goal is to estimate consumer surplus from visiting a given site then the analysis should focus on estimating the alternative cost of time. Unfortunately, in the cases when \(\frac{{\partial U/\partial T_{i} }}{\lambda } > 0\) , VTTS will underestimate the true value of time and the more similar the value of travel is to the value of time on-site, the larger the discrepancy between VTTS and the value of time in terms of lost opportunities will be.

1.2 Valuing the Opportunity Cost of Travel Time in Recreation Demand Models: Previous Research

The incorporation of the value of travel time in the TCM studies has been a source of concern since the earliest applications of this method (e.g., Clawson and Knetsch 1966 ; Johnson 1966 ). Researchers disagreed not only about how much the travel time is worth but also whether it should be included it in the model at all. Cesario ( 1976 ) provided an early cogent discussion of the incorporation of the value of time into travel cost models. Despite the decades of research into the value of time, Randall’s ( 1994 ) observation that “the cost of travel time remains an empirical mystery” remains valid and estimating the value of travel time (or, in most cases, rather the opportunity cost of time) remains a frequently discussed problem in the literature on TCM (e.g., Fletcher et al. 1990 ; Garrod and Willis 1999 ; Hanley and Barbier 2009 ).

Early on McConnell ( 1975 ) stressed the need to estimate the value of time before incorporating it in the demand function. However, uncovering the rate of substitution between money and time was long considered empirically intractable (as these trade-offs are endogenous and unobservable), even if conceptually possible. Cesario’s ( 1976 ) suggestion that commuter’s travel time values of 25–50% of an individual’s wage rate was widely adopted. Using a fraction of wage rate has remained probably the most common approach, with the compromise value of 33% being the most broadly accepted level (Hellerstein and Mendelsohn 1993 ; Englin and Cameron 1996 ; Garrod and Willis 1999 ; Gürlük and Rehber 2008 ; Egan et al. 2009 ; Huhtala and Lankia 2012 ). Critics of the wage-based approach note that it makes little sense for those without reported wages, the method would suggest their marginal utility of time is zero. That is clearly not the case (Feather and Shaw 1999 ; Parsons 2003 ). Footnote 1

Englin and Shonkwiler ( 1995 ) developed a model linking a count travel cost to a confirmatory factor analytic model. The confirmatory factor analytic portion allowed a travel time value to be imputed for each individual and incorporated into the cost of travel. In a further development, Feather and Shaw ( 1999 ) used shadow wages (the values of extra units of leisure time) as the opportunity cost of travel time and compared this with previous approaches (using a fraction of wage rate and hedonic wage equations). On average, their estimates were better adjusted to the observed wage rates for different employment categories of respondents, compared with the wage rate predicted by the hedonic model.

Recent work has focused on the relationship between one’s work and life schedule and the value of time in recreational travel. The early discussion of these issues was put forth by Bockstael et al. ( 1987 ) who proposed a general framework on how to incorporate time in TCM studies, based on insights from the labor literature. Demand for time depends on whether an individual can freely substitute recreation for work (interior solution) or has fixed work hours (corner solution). Most recently, Larson and Lew ( 2014 ) empirically implemented a system of joint labor-recreation equations to capture these effects. Palmquist et al. ( 2010 ) employed a joint revealed stated preference approach to deal with fundamental lack of substitutability of recreation time for other forms of time. Both of these efforts seek a structural analysis of the value of time that looks at the relationship between the demand for time and hence value and flexibility to substitute time.

A second recent strand of work has focused on revealed valuations of travel time. Fezzi et al. ( 2014 ) utilized a natural experiment where recreationists had a choice of a toll road which was faster or not paying a toll and taking more time to reach the recreation site. This is a novel approach and very robust but it is also specific to a particular site and so will be subject to the usual limitations if the values are transferred to other settings. Wolff ( 2014 ) utilized speeding behavior as a function of gasoline price to identify the value of time. This is also revealed preference approach and so is excellent for the area studied but again the values must be transferred to use in other settings.

Early suggestions to combine TCM with contingent valuation or contingent behavior questions (Cameron 1992a , b ; Adamowicz et al. 1994 ; Englin and Cameron 1996 ) explored the methodological issues without paying specific attention to the opportunity cost of time. For example, Englin and Cameron ( 1996 ) added contingent behavior questions to a TCM study but these questions referred to general trip costs and not specifically to the opportunity cost of time. Nevertheless, such an approach makes it possible to impose exogenously varying travel costs and could be applied to opportunity cost of time too. Álvarez-Farizo et al. ( 2001 ) adopted contingent valuation to estimate the value of leisure time for use in recreational models and confirmed a significant variation in leisure time values. Building on Shaw ( 1992 ), Casey et al. ( 1995 ) offered an alternative approach, indicating that individual preferences regarding time are better reflected by the opportunity costs of time associated with a particular aspect of recreation than the wage. After all, the latter measures the trade-off between work and leisure more generally. They complemented a standard travel cost survey with a contingent valuation question about peoples’ willingness to accept compensation to forgo a precisely defined recreational experience and used these results to derive the value of leisure time. Ovaskainen et al. ( 2012 ) directly elicited a stated value of time using a contingent valuation survey. Finally, Lloyd-Smith et al. ( 2019 ) in the context of recreation demand for fishing trips found that individual value of leisure time is substantially different from one’s implied wage rate.

In light of the above challenges of incorporating meaningful estimates of the opportunity cost of time into recreational demand models, in what follows we propose to combine TCM with a DCE that would indicate how much each respondent values travel time. Compared to most of the above ideas, ours is more flexible and it is very precise in that we obtain specific estimates on the opportunity cost of time for each respondent in any potential setting. We explain this approach by first reviewing the methodology required by the TCM and DCE studies, with a particular focus on econometric derivation of individual-specific values of travel time savings. We then move to an empirical illustration of our approach, which is compared with traditional treatments of value of travel time savings. Our case study not only serves as an example of the methodology we propose, but also illustrates that the usual approach of assuming that respondents’ values of travel time savings are proportional to their wages is largely unfounded. The last section offers discussion of the results and conclusions.

2 Methods and Econometric Treatment

2.1 the travel cost method.

The individual travel cost method treats trips to a site as the quantity demanded, while the cost of the trip as the price of access to the site. These assumptions result in a demand function of the following form:

where \(r_{i}\) is the number of trips taken by individual \(i\) to a given site during a given time period, \(p_{i}\) is the cost of access to the site (which usually consists of the cost of travel and opportunity cost of travel time), and \({\mathbf{z}}_{i}\) is a vector of individual characteristics that are believed to influence the number of trips an individual takes.

In this setting, the consumer surplus associated with accessing the site by an individual \(i\) is represented by:

where \(p_{i}^{0}\) is the current trip cost to the site and \(p_{i}^{ \cdot }\) is the cost level at which the number of trips goes to zero, also called individual \(i\) ’s ‘choke price’.

A standard practice is to model single-site recreation demand functions using count data distributions. The two most frequently used count models are Poisson and Negative Binomial. These models are flexible enough to handle truncation, a large number of zero trips in the data, and preference heterogeneity. The main advantage of the Poisson model is that it is a member of the linear exponential family and so its parameters are unbiased as long as the underlying demand relationship is linear exponential. However, the Poisson distribution has the property of equi-dispersion—the first two moments of a distribution are equal, i.e., \(E\left( Y \right) = \mu = V\left( Y \right)\) . If a particular data set does not satisfy this assumption, as is in the case of our study, then more efficient estimates of the parameters can be obtained from the negative binomial distribution as it does not require equi-dispersion.

A second area of consideration is the method used to sample the trip data. If the data was sampled on-site the frequency of visitation by a user affects the likelihood of being in the sample. This sampling bias is referred to as endogenous stratification. The more frequently one visits a site the more likely they are to be sampled. A second issue is that only visitors can possibly be sampled. As a result, the sample is also truncated at zero. The problem of endogenous stratification and truncation in the context of travel cost modeling has been addressed for the Poisson model by Shaw ( 1988 ). Englin and Shonkwiler ( 1995 ) extended the analysis to the truncated and endogenously stratified negative binomial model. Englin and Shonkwiler ( 1995 ) accommodated three features of on-site samples concerning count data: over-dispersion, truncation at zero, and endogenous stratification due to oversampling of frequent users of the site. In this model, the probability of individual \(i\) making \(y_{i}\) trips to the site is given by:

where \(\varGamma\) represents the gamma function, \(\lambda_{i}\) is the mean, which is typically modeled as a function of explanatory variables and \(\alpha_{i}\) is the over-dispersion parameter. Footnote 2

2.2 Discrete Choice Experiments

In environmental economics stated preference methods are commonly used for modeling consumers’ preferences and valuation (Carson and Czajkowski 2014 ). Respondents’ choices are typically modeled in a random utility framework, which assumes that the utility associated with any choice alternative can be divided into a sum of contributions that can be observed by a researcher, and a component that cannot, hence is assumed random. Specifically, consider the following empirical specification of a random utility multinomial choice model:

where \(U_{ij}\) represents respondent \(i\) ’s utility associated with selecting alternative \(j\) out of a set of \(J\) available alternatives, \({\mathbf{x}}_{ij}\) is a vector of respondent- and alternative-specific choice attributes, i.e., goods or their characteristics, and \({\varvec{\upbeta}}_{i}\) represents a vector of individual-specific taste parameters associated with marginal utilities of the choice attributes. Assumptions regarding parametric distributions of the taste parameters, such that \({\varvec{\upbeta}}_{i} \sim {\mathbf{f}}\left( {{\mathbf{b}},{\varvec{\Sigma}}} \right)\) , where \({\mathbf{b}}\) is a vector of sample means and \({\varvec{\Sigma}}\) is a variance–covariance matrix, allows to account for unobserved preference heterogeneity and possibly—correlations between random taste parameters.

The stochastic component of the utility function \(\left( \varepsilon \right)\) may be interpreted as resulting from researcher’s inability to observe all attributes of choice and all significant characteristics of respondents (McFadden 1976 ), or as decision maker’s choice from a set of his decision rules. Random utility theory is transformed into different econometric models by making assumptions about the distribution of the random error term and the random parameters. Typically, \(\varepsilon_{ij}\) is assumed to be independently and identically (iid) Extreme Value Type 1 distributed across individuals and alternatives. When unobserved preference heterogeneity is allowed in a way presented above, this leads to a Random Parameters Mixed Logit (RP-MXL) model (McFadden and Train 2000 ).

In what follows, we utilize Bayesian framework for estimating a RP-MXL model and deriving individual-level taste parameters and, as a result, individual-specific VTTS. The advantages of Bayesian approach over classical estimation include easier identification of a global maximum of the likelihood function, and handling correlated random parameters (Huber and Train 2001 ). In addition, in a Bayesian approach identification of individual-level parameters is less of an issue than in classical approach, since in extreme cases the prior can provide the necessary information.

Bayesian estimation procedures for the RP-MXL model do not require simulating choice probabilities. Instead, the likelihood of observing individual \(i\) making a sequence of \(T\) choices \({\mathbf{Y}}_{i} = \left\{ {y_{i1} , \ldots ,y_{it} , \ldots y_{iT} } \right\}\) is the product of standard logit formulas, conditional on \({\varvec{\upbeta}}\) :

The unconditional probability is the integral of ( 9 ) with respect to all values of \({\varvec{\upbeta}}_{i}\) , weighted by their multivariate probability density \(\psi \left( {{\varvec{\upbeta}}_{i} } \right)\) :

The Bayesian approach requires specifying priors for the model parameters \({\mathbf{b}}\) , \({\varvec{\Sigma}}\) and \({\varvec{\upbeta}}_{i}\) for all

\(i = 1..N\) . Typically, a diffuse normal distribution (with zero means and diagonal matrix of arbitrarily large variances \({\varvec{\Theta}}\) , allowing for almost flat distribution) is used as a prior for \({\mathbf{b}}\) , \({\mathbf{b}} \sim MVN\left( {0,{\varvec{\Theta}}} \right)\) , and inverted Wishart distribution (with the number of degrees of freedom \(K\) equal to the length of \({\mathbf{b}}\) , and parameter \(K{\mathbf{I}}\) , where \({\mathbf{I}}\) is a \(K\) -dimensional identity matrix) is used as a prior for \({\varvec{\Sigma}}\) , \({\varvec{\Sigma}} \sim IW\left( {K,K{\mathbf{I}}} \right)\) . The priors for each individual’s taste parameters \({\varvec{\upbeta}}_{i}\) are proportional to the assumed (population-level) distributions of taste parameters times the priors on \({\mathbf{b}}\) and \({\varvec{\Sigma}}\) ; as an aside, because of this hierarchy of parameters this procedure is often referred to as hierarchical Bayes. As a result, denoting choice sequences of all individuals at all choice occasions as \({\mathbf{Y}}\) , the joint posterior distribution on \({\mathbf{b}}\) , \({\varvec{\Sigma}}\) and each \({\varvec{\upbeta}}_{i}\) is:

Since using the parametric distributions which impose bounds on taste parameters may make direct drawing from the joint posterior distribution difficult, some variant of Metropolis–Hasting algorithm is usually used (Train 2009 ). Footnote 3

The approach that we propose in this paper extends the traditional TCM by utilizing individual-specific VTTS. In order to make this possible and, at the same time, allow for preference heterogeneity it is crucial to obtain individual-level taste parameter estimates. Although in this paper we adopt a Bayesian approach, Huber and Train ( 2001 ) showed that reliable individual-level parameters for discrete choice models can be obtained irrespectively of the estimation or inference framework. Within a Bayesian framework, the distribution of coefficients across the population is estimated and used as a prior, which combined with individual’s choices results in posterior estimates of each individual’s tastes (Rossi et al. 1996 ; Allenby and Rossi 1998 ). Similarly, in a classical setting, applying Bayes theorem, i.e., combining maximum likelihood estimates of the population distribution with individual choices, makes derivation of individual-specific parameter estimates possible (Revelt and Train 2000 ). Huber and Train ( 2001 ) showed that these approaches lead to largely equivalent results.

3 Empirical Study

In order to investigate differences resulting from applying individual-level estimates of travel time versus the traditionally assumed value of time we designed and implemented a joint TCM-DCE study in the context of recreational birdwatching.

3.1 Study Site, Experimental Design and Survey Administration

The study site selected for this application was Żywkowo, one of Polish ‘stork villages’—a term used by a recent New York Times article about them (Whitaker 2015 ). A stork village is a common name for a village with a white stork ( Ciconia ciconia ) breeding colony, often inhabited by more storks than people. Żywkowo, the best-known stork village in Poland, has approximately 40 white stork nests and 10 households, while it receives approximately 2000–5000 tourists annually, many of whom come from abroad. Żywkowo lays in the north-east of Poland, on the periphery of one of the most attractive parts of the country to tourists, the Masurian Lake District. It is not located near any major tourist attraction and is relatively far from larger cities; in addition, since there are no other attractions in the village it is visited solely because of birds, and more specifically—because of white storks.

The questionnaire was designed to collect the usual data necessary for a TCM study. We asked where the tourists came from, distinguishing between their most recent stop (if they visited more than one place during their trips) and their place of residence. We also asked how long the travel took, what means of transportation were used and the number of people travelling in a party. In order to identify respondents who, in general, had positive willingness to pay for travel time savings we asked if they had wished their travel time to the site was shorter. Footnote 4 After that, respondents who expressed general interest in making their travel time shorter were asked to participate in hypothetical discrete choice tasks designed to reveal their WTP for travel time savings. Finally, respondents were asked socio-economic questions, providing information about their age, gender, income, level of education, and basic birdwatching preferences. Questionnaires were available in Polish, German and English. Footnote 5

The DCE part of the survey was introduced as follows:

Now we would like to ask you to take part in an exercise that involves making some choices. Imagine that the trip from the last place of your stay could be shorter. However, it would require an additional cost. You would have to personally pay this cost and it would increase the current cost of your trip. Please assume that shortening the trip would not decrease the costs of your travel. You could spend the time that you would save in any preferred way, for example resting or working. In a moment you we will show you several hypothetical situations that present different combinations of time saved and the related cost. In each case, please choose a variant that you consider the best – from your own point of view (please think about yourself only). Bear in mind that the additional cost would reduce your budget available for other purposes. This is why we ask you to treat this cost as if you would really have to pay it. If you would not be willing to pay anything extra for the saved time, choose Alternative 1 – status quo.

The DCE utilized up to 6 choice tasks per respondent. Each choice task consisted of 3 alternatives—one status quo alternative associated with no travel time savings and no costs, and two alternatives associated with different travel time savings and additional cost. There were 3 versions of the DCE questions which differed in the utilized attribute levels, depending on respondent’s travel time and an additional version for self-administered surveys that used relative travel time reduction levels. The attribute levels are presented in Table  1 .

The design of each DCE version was generated using NGENE. We optimized each experimental design for the D-efficiency of an MNL model using Bayesian priors (Ferrini and Scarpa 2007 ). All prior estimates were assumed to be normally distributed, with their means derived from the MNL model estimated on the dataset from the pilot survey, and standard deviations equal to 0.25 of each parameter’s mean (with an absolute minimum for means that were very close to zero). Additionally, the design included constraints on attribute level combinations, to rule out dominated or repetitive alternatives.

Tourists visiting Żywkowo were surveyed on site between April and September of 2011, that is, since when the storks returned from their spring migration to when they left for autumn migration. Questionnaires were available to tourists visiting an exhibition room. Tourists were prompted to take part in the study by local employees and, additionally, by interviewers who assisted the local staff at times when the tourists were the most numerous. In 2011, 2850 tourists visited the exhibition room, of whom 583 agreed to complete the questionnaire, resulting in a response rate above 20%. Footnote 6 Socio-demographic characteristics of the sample and main descriptive statistics of the journeys are presented in Table  2 .

3.2 Deriving Respondent-Specific Values of Travel Time Savings with Discrete Choice Experiment Approach

We start by presenting the results of the discrete choice experiment estimated for respondents who indicated that they wished their journey to the study site had been shorter ( n  = 247, 47%). Respondents who answered ‘No’ were assumed not to be ‘in the market’ for shortening their journey, and hence their WTP for travel time savings was 0. Footnote 7

The RP-MXL model was estimated using the Bayesian procedures described in Sect.  2.2. The choice attributes included travel time savings, cost and an alternative specific constant associated with the status quo alternative. All taste parameters were assumed random. Since economic theory indicates that utility associated with (negative) cost and travel time savings (for respondents who indicated that they wished their journey had been shorter) cannot be negative, we assumed that population-level parameters of these attributes were log-normally distributed. The parameter of the alternative specific constant for the status quo alternative was assumed to follow normal distribution.

The estimation was performed in Matlab. Footnote 8 In our application, we used 10 5 iterations for ‘burn-in’ (the iterations used by Metropolis–Hasting algorithm within which the draws converge to the target, conditional posterior distribution), and after that we retained every 11th iteration result for the total of 10 5 iterations used to conduct inference, i.e., from a classical perspective, deriving estimates of the parameters. Footnote 9 Finally, we used 10 6 draws per individual to simulate the estimated distributions of random parameters and to calculate simulated log-likelihood value. The step length for the Metropolis–Hasting algorithm was set to 0.3, well within the range suggested by Gelman et al. ( 2003 ).

The estimation results are presented in Table  3 . The first column represents the reference MNL model. The improvement in model fit from the MNL to the RP-MXL model with correlated parameters, as indicated by Akaike information criterion (AIC) and Bayesian information criterion (BIC), is an evidence of substantial heterogeneity in respondents’ preferences. This is confirmed by relatively large estimates of standard deviations of population parameters. The results of a likelihood ratio tests show that indeed, all parameters should be modeled as random.

The estimation results presented above allowed us to derive individual-specific parameters in a fashion described in Sect.  2.2. These parameters were in turn used to simulate Footnote 10 individual-level willingness to pay for travel time savings, following Small and Rosen ( 1981 ) and Hanemann ( 1984 ):

where \(\mu\) is the marginal utility of income (the parameter on price), \({\varvec{\upbeta}}\) is vector of estimated parameters of the indirect utility function, \({\mathbf{x}}_{0}\) are the levels of the attributes in the reference situation and \({\mathbf{x}}_{1}\) are the levels of the attributes in the improved situation. In our case, we assumed two alternatives ( \(n = 2\) ; status quo and non-status quo) and the improvement in the form of 1-h travel time reduction, which occurred in the non-status quo alternative of \({\mathbf{x}}_{1}\) .

Descriptive statistics of these individual-specific values of travel time savings for the sample of our respondents are presented in Table  4 . For comparison, the table also includes the statistics for respondents’ wage rates. Footnote 11

The results of this exercise allow for a few interesting conclusions. First of all, even a relatively simple discrete choice experiment can allow for calculating respondent-specific values of travel time savings. The descriptive statistics presented in Table  4 show that individual-specific values of WTP for travel time savings are plausible for virtually all respondents in our sample.

Secondly, we find that all respondents’ mean value of 1-h travel time savings is very close 1/2 of their mean wage rate. However, on closer inspection, 47% of respondents declared that they did not wish their journey was shorter, implying VTTS = 0. In addition, 29.81% of those who were generally ‘in the market’ for shortening their travel times still made choices which implied very low VTTS (e.g., did not choose the costly improvement alternative in any of the choice tasks). Footnote 12 Interestingly, mean VTTS of those who indicated they wished their journey was shorter is close to their (full) mean wage rate. Finally, we note that the correlation of respondents’ VTTS and their wage rate is very low (0.0411 for all respondents, 0.1191 for those who declared they wished their journey was shorter).

We investigate the relationship between respondents’ VTTS and wage rate further using graphical illustration provided in Fig.  1 . If VTTS and wage rates were correlated, we would expect a positive linear relationship. Instead, we find that respondents’ WTP for shortening their trip is largely independent of their wage rate.

figure 1

Respondents’ wage rates and implied values of travel time savings

Overall, our results do not support using respondents’ wage rate as a proxy for their VTTS. Instead, we argue for utilizing stated preference methods for measuring individual level VTTS and in what follows, we demonstrate substantial differences resulting from utilizing individual-level versus aggregated versus traditional assumptions regarding the value of travel time in travel cost models.

3.2.1 Individual Heterogeneity with Respect to VTTS

In order to provide an insight into respondents’ heterogeneity with respect to their VTTS we present the logit model for ‘market participation’—respondents’ answers to the question if they (in general) would prefer that their journey was shorter and a simple linear regression model in which individual-specific VTTS are explained with respondents’ socio-demographic variables (Table  5 ).

The results show that respondents whose journeys were longer were more likely to answer that they indeed wished their journey had been shorter; the relationship is convex, as indicated by the negative coefficient associated with the travel time squared. Footnote 13 These results coincide with individual specific VTTS—respondents who had to travel longer were willing to pay more to shorten their journey (although at a decreasing rate). Additionally, we find that respondents with medium or high level of education are more likely to state that they wish their journey was shorter. Respondents from larger households are also statistically willing to pay more for travel time reduction, although this last effect is counterfeited for respondents with children. Finally, we note that once respondents’ socio-demographic characteristics are controlled for, their wage was not a significant explanatory variable of willing to shorten one’s journey, Footnote 14 and only weakly significant for explaining their individual VTTS. This is in stark contrast with the common practice of utilizing fraction of one’s income as a proxy for their VTTS (Parsons 2017 ).

These results have profound implications. Since respondents whose traveling times are larger have higher WTP for shortening their journey it clearly follows that using mean VTTS for every respondent in the sample will negatively bias the cost of travel time. This is because observations with higher individual-specific VTTS have higher weights in the utility function (more hours multiplied with higher cost per hour). In addition, since respondents’ VTTS appears statistically independent from their wage, using individual-specific wage rates as a proxy of VTTS is not convincing approach either. We illustrate this finding with the comparison of different modeling approaches in the next section.

3.3 Travel Cost Method with Consumer-Specific Values of Travel Time Savings

In this section we present the estimation results of 5 travel cost models with different assumptions with respect to respondents’ VTTS. Generally, visitor \(i\) ’s expected number of trips can be calculated as:

which serves as our travel cost recreation demand function. The \(TC_{i}\) represents individual \(i\) ’s cost associated with reaching the stork village and \({\mathbf{Z}}_{i}\) is a vector of individual characteristics that are considered to influence the number of trips \(i\) takes (in our case, since we intended to keep our approach as simple as possible, we only used a constant).

The average cost of traveling 1 km was assumed to be 0.45 PLN Footnote 15 ; however, when calculating cost per person we took a travelling party size into account. As far as the VTTS is concerned, the following alternative specifications were used:

VTTS = 1/3 of respondent’s wage rate;

VTTS = respondent’s wage rate;

VTTS = mean WTP derived from the MNL model;

VTTS = individual-specific WTP derived from the RP-MXL model.

In all cases, we only included the cost associated with the travel time for respondents who indicated that they wished their journey was shorter. The resulting travel costs, calculated under different assumptions with respect to VTTS, are presented in Table  6 .

We estimated the count data models in a Bayesian framework, applying the independence chain Metropolis–Hastings algorithm with a multivariate t distribution (with mean \(\left( {{\hat{\mathbf{\beta }}}} \right)\) equal to the mode of the posterior kernel, and variance equal inverted negative Hessian resulting from the maximum likelihood estimator subroutine evaluated at \({\hat{\mathbf{\beta }}}\) ) Footnote 16 as a candidate-generating density (Chib et al. 1998 ; Davis and Moeltner 2010 ). The Gibbs Sampler was implemented with 100,000 burn-in draws and 10,000 retained draws. Footnote 17

The estimation results are presented in Table  7 . As expected, the travel cost coefficient is negative and statistically significant at the 1% level in all the models. The constant and the over-dispersion parameter \(\alpha_{i}\) are also highly significant. Footnote 18 It is impossible to directly compare the models in terms of fit, as each one is essentially estimated on a different dataset, and hence they are not presented in Table  7 . A common theme is that the intercept term is relatively stable across specifications ranging from − 5.4125 to − 5.4966, virtually indistinguishable from each other statistically. The over-dispersion parameters are also similar. The slope parameters while not statistically different at conventional test levels follow the usual pattern of higher values of time flattening the slope of the estimated demand curve.

We now turn to presenting the welfare measures associated with the different VTTS assumptions made in Models 1 to 5. Consumer surpluses (CS) per person per trip were calculated as an inverse of the estimated travel cost parameter \(\left( {{{ - 1} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{ - 1} {\beta_{TC} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\beta_{TC} }}} \right)\) . The 95% confidence intervals were simulated. The results are reported in Table  8 .

As the parameter estimates for the demand functions suggest will happen, the welfare estimates for flatter demand curves (ones with higher values for time) are higher. The individual random parameters model provides the highest welfare measures, however, all the CS are plausible (they are in the range of CS reported in other TCM studies conducted in Poland, e.g., Panasiuk 2001 ; Bartczak et al. 2008 ; Bartczak et al. 2012 ; Czajkowski et al. 2015 ; Kulczyk et al. 2016 ; Czajkowski et al. 2018 ; Gawrońska et al. 2018 ; Wiśniewska et al. 2018 ).

4 Discussion and Conclusions

In this paper we propose to combine the usual TCM data with respondent-specific estimates of the value of travel time savings. Although slightly more complicated and more strenuous for respondents, this approach is much more informative than utilizing values of times derived from respondents’ wage rate or stated preference results assuming common value for all individuals in the sample.

Our approach is different from those proposed so far in that we do not just extrapolate the appropriate wage rate based on the respondents’ socio-economic data combined with other sources, nor any structural analysis of the value of time for our respondents. Our DCE questions are more flexible than the approach of Fezzi et al. ( 2014 ), in that they are general and not specific to our study. At the same time, this approach limits the scope of researcher judgment necessary to estimate the opportunity cost of travel time, and it reduces the need for external data to be combined with survey data in an attempt to calculate the opportunity cost of travel time in a structural way.

In light of the difficulties and ambiguities related to the opportunity cost of travel time, some authors decided not to incorporate time costs in their travel cost models (Hanley et al. 2003 ; Alberini and Longo 2006 ; Alberini et al. 2007 ; Fleming and Cook 2008 ). Footnote 19 One of the reasons for this approach is the apprehension that incorporating time might bias the coefficient on the price downwards. Another problem might be that time spent in travel might have a value on its own—travelling might be generating utility for some travelers, resulting from enjoying landscapes and amenities, deriving pleasure from a particular means of transportation, adventure-seeking, variety-seeking and be otherwise productively used (Chavas et al. 1989 ; Lyons and Urry 2005 ; Mokhtarian 2005 ; Ory and Mokhtarian 2005 ). In our study, 47% of respondents declared that they would wish to reduce the travel time of their journey. These results are consistent with previous studies investigating the value of time spent on leisure journeys, which highlight that sometimes the time spent in travel may be worth more than on the final spot (Anable and Gatersleben 2005 ; Larson and Lew 2005 ). Indeed, Żywkowo is located in a remote but particularly picturesque part of the country, with narrow roads lined with large trees, and several other tourist attractions in the region. Clearly, our study helps to challenge the common assumption that “travel is a disutility to be minimized” (Mokhtarian 2005 , p. 93).

Our study indicates that it is not necessary nor adequate to use a fraction of hourly earnings because the opportunity cost of time can be measured more accurately by allowing respondents to express their preferences regarding the time they spend in travel. In this way, we move even further with the argument that the opportunity cost of travel time is defined endogenously—it is a function of visitor’s characteristics. We explicitly account for the opportunity cost of travel time perceived by respondents, as opposed to the real cost of travel time they may incur (Amoako-Tuffour and Martínez-Espiñeira 2012 ). Such a flexible approach allows us to account for the fact that travel time is decided by each individual who can choose longer or shorter routes, considering the consumptive value of travel time. The idea that the valuation of travel time is highly subjective was present in the discussion already since Cesario ( 1976 ). Indeed, we observed substantial heterogeneity in respondents’ preferences in our study, particularly with 47% of respondents declaring that they would not wish their travel time was shorter, and the VTTS of the other respondents very weakly correlated with their wage rates.

Our study has several limitations and it is important to acknowledge them. First, while the dominant empirical approach to infer VTTS in the transportation literature is based on experiments, in which respondents are asked to make hypothetical choices or personal travel time gains in exchange for travel costs paid from their own budget, this approach is no longer in line with the state-of-the-art stated preference valuation methodology. In particular, our DCE was not consequential (Vossler et al. 2012 ), it relayed on epsilon truthfulness and hence did not satisfy the incentive compatibility conditions (Carson and Groves 2007 ) and did not satisfy several other recommendations for stated preference studies (Champ et al. 2017 ; Johnston et al. 2017 ). As a result, we are unable to claim, that the estimated VTTS are unbiased. How to incorporate VTTS questions in a DCE component of a TCM survey remains an important area for future research (not only in the case of our study, but transport literature in general). Second, the hourly ‘wage rates’ that we used for comparisons were calculated on the basis of household income per adult. It remains an open question if household or individual income should be considered, as the basis for consumers’ purchasing decisions in the context of time savings. Finally, our study applied a single-site version of the TCM. Following Von Haefen ( 2002 ), all substitute sites are captured in the constant of our model. We acknowledge this as a possible limitation of our study. Footnote 20

Many applied researchers are rather conservative in their assumptions about how much the opportunity cost of time might add to the value of a visited site and preferred to use the lower bounds of the wage rate (Neher et al. 2013 ). For example, Hynes et al. ( 2009 ) suggested that it would be useful to determine individual opportunity costs of travel time to avoid a potential bias related to assuming an excessively high wage fraction as a reference. Meanwhile, a comparison of our approach with the key alternative specifications of the opportunity cost of time show that recreationists may actually value their time higher than it has been expected so far. Consumer surplus calculated with the RP-MXL model was more than twice as high as in the case of not including the travel time at all, or when the opportunity cost of travel time was assumed to be 1/3 of the wage rate. It was even higher than if the opportunity cost of travel time equaled full wage rate of those who did not say they wished their journey had been shorter.

More broadly, our study indicates a need to incorporate various components of the travel cost and to do so in a respondent-specific way. Indeed, travel is a complex issue, especially when related to recreational purposes, and it bears many unmeasured qualities which may be differently perceived and valued by the different travelers (Salomon and Mokhtarian 1998 ). Our study shows an opportunity to integrate different valuation methods and thus practically use the fact that they refer to different issues and can provide complementary information. Our empirical illustration of valuing recreational birdwatching in a stork village demonstrates the feasibility of this approach. It also shows that, as the minimum, future studies could directly ask respondents if they wish their journey was shorter, and include value of travel time of only those who agreed. In our case, and in line with Jara-Díaz et al. ( 2008 ) and Lloyd-Smith et al. ( 2019 ), those who were willing to pay to make their journey shorter declared WTP per hour on average close to their full wage rate, although more evidence is needed to verify if this finding is universal.

Notably, the transportation literature focusing on the estimation of the value of time has moved on from the rough approach of taking 33% of wage to more fine-tuned estimates taking into account, among other things, trip purpose, transport mode and difference between drivers and passengers (e.g., Börjesson and Eliasson 2014 ; Sartori et al. 2014 ; Mouter and Chorus 2016 ).

Amoako-Tuffour and Martínez-Espiñeira ( 2012 ) took this reasoning further and allowed the over-dispersion parameter \(\alpha_{i}\) to vary according to respondent characteristics (and they used their survey data to indicate which fraction of the wage rate best represented the respondents’ opportunity cost of travel time, making also this parameter a function of the respondents’ characteristics).

Interestingly, the results of the estimation procedure are asymptotically equivalent to the classical, maximum likelihood estimator. The results can thus be given a dual—classical and Bayesian—interpretation.

The exact wording of the question was: “Would you prefer the trip from the last place of your last stay to be shorter? (a) Yes; (b) No; (c) I do not know”. Respondents who answered (a) or (c) were considered to be ‘in the market’ for shortening their journey time.

More details about the survey are available in Czajkowski et al. ( 2014 ).

We are unable to compare the sample characteristics with the characteristics of the target population because the characteristics of the target population (visitors of the study site) are unavailable. However, we note that share of surveyed visitors was relatively large, the interviews were collected throughout the entire season and the respondents were selected randomly from the visitors available at a time (for parties traveling together, only respondents who actually paid for the trip were surveyed; in the case of more than one person paying for the trip (e.g., a family with joint budget or a party who shared costs)—the respondent was selected randomly).

This is consistent with early theoretical contributions to microeconomic time allocation theory and travel time valuation, which recognized that, in some cases, travel may be enjoyable (e.g., Becker 1965 ; Johnson 1966 ; Evans 1972 ). Another line of research related to why people do not want their trip to be shorter is related to non-shortest-path route choice. There is now numerous evidence of this type behavior (Agrawal et al. 2008 ; Bovy and Stern 2012 ; Broach et al. 2012 ). These studies evidence that people do not always choose the shortest, fastest, or cheapest route to their destination. It is well recognized in the transportation literature that positive utility of travel may be at play, if travelers want to travel farther than necessary or if they choose more scenic or enjoyable but out-of-the way paths.

The dataset and software codes for the models used in this paper are available from http://czaj.org/research/supplementary-materials .

We retained only every 11th draw in order to reduce the amount of correlation among the draws.

Only respondents who declared that they wished their journey was shorter were included in this analysis; the others were assumed not to be willing to pay for travel time savings (VTTS = 0). In simulation we accounted for effective means of the distributions which were modelled as truncated normal.

The wage rate was calculated as net (after tax) household income (including all sources of income, such as salaries, pensions, rents etc.) divided by the number of adults in a household and divided by 160 (regular number of working hours per month). While this is not strictly the individual’s wage per hour, it represents the family budget constraint, which is often the more appropriate measure of purchasing decisions (Lindhjem and Navrud 2009 ). For respondents who refused to disclose their household income, we arbitrarily assumed their income was equal to the sample mean.

As noted by one of the reviewers, this is a likely indication of a status quo bias that may have implications for our estimated consumer surplus indicators.

This result is consistent with the transportation literature findings that the satisfaction with the travel experience and travel liking tends to decrease with longer trip distances or durations (Rasouli and Timmermans 2014 ; Milakis et al. 2015 ; Morris and Guerra 2015 ) (e.g., Rasouli and Timmermans 2014 ; Milakis et al. 2015 ; Morris and Guerra 2015 ).

Wage remains insignificant even if (possibly correlated) education is not included as an explanatory variable, and if it is the only explanatory variable in the model.

We used the official average operating cost according to the Polish Automobile Association. This rate is commonly used for reimbursing employees who use private vehicles for official business.

The tuner elements for these t-distributions were set as the degrees of freedom = 8 for means and a scalar 2 for the variance. These settings led to desirable acceptance rates and efficiency measures.

As an aside, we have also tried to combine the two estimation steps into one. This can theoretically be done by saving the appropriate number of iteration- and individual-specific parameters from the discrete choice part (and hence iteration- and individual-specific VTTS values) and utilizing them for each of the iterations conducted in step 2. In other words, each iteration in the estimation of the count data model would use a different explanatory vector, thus preserving the conditionality that links the two equations. However, this approach turned out to be infeasible, due to some iteration- and individual-specific VTTS being undefined or plus/minus infinity, particularly when the value of the cost parameter was drawn very close to 0. As a result, the estimation of the count data model could not proceed without additional assumptions (such as assuming that VTTS of such respondents was 0, or sample mean). In addition to the independence chain version of the Metropolis–Hastings algorithm which requires optimizing the LL function (and hence evaluating gradients) for each iteration and causes additional problems if some of the observations are not real numbers, we tried a simpler, random walk version of this algorithm. This approach also turned out infeasible for simultaneous estimation because even without the necessity to calculate gradients the value of the log-likelihood function was often undefined. We acknowledge the statistical inefficiency of a two-step estimation procedure, which is likely to bias the standard errors of the model estimates presented in Table  7 .

On a technical note, since the candidate parameters for the count data model are derived from a multivariate t distribution, we found that with sufficiently large variance, every so often the candidate draw for the \(\alpha\) parameter was negative. This caused numerical problems, as the gamma function (see Eq.  6 ) is only defined for positive values. In order to impose this theory-driven constraint we revised Eq. ( 6 ) in such a way, that \(\alpha = \exp \left( {\alpha^{ * } } \right)\) and optimized for \(\alpha^{ * }\) (similarly to the method proposed by Carson and Czajkowski 2019 ). This proved a convenient way to ensure that \(\alpha\) has no support for negative values, while not changing the log-likelihood function. Similarly, we found that expanding the logarithm of Eq. ( 6 ) in such a way that one uses the log gamma instead of gamma function allows to avoid further numerical problems with exploding values for some iterations.

An alternative to using the opportunity cost of time was proposed by Shrestha et al. ( 2002 ) and later applied by Hanley and Barbier ( 2009 ). They included travel time in hours as an extra variable, alongside travel cost. The estimated time that respondents would be willing to spend in travel can then be translated into economic value, when combined with information about their willingness to pay money in a utility-theoretic framework (Larson et al. 2004 ). In addition to a travel cost model, one can also develop a separate model of transportation mode choice to estimate the value of travel time, providing information on how time is valued versus the cost of travel (Hausman et al. 1995 ).

We considered including other ‘stork villages’ in the analysis, but the second most popular and recognized such site (Kłopot) is located 600 km away, on the opposite side of Poland.

Adamowicz W, Louviere J, Williams M (1994) Combining revealed and stated preference methods for valuing environmental amenities. J Environ Econ Manag 26(3):271–292

Google Scholar  

Agrawal AW, Schlossberg M, Irvin K (2008) How far, by which route and why? A spatial analysis of pedestrian preference. J Urban Des 13(1):81–98

Alberini A, Longo A (2006) Combining the travel cost and contingent behavior methods to value cultural heritage sites: evidence from Armenia. J Cult Econ 30(4):287–304

Alberini A, Zanatta V, Rosato P (2007) Combining actual and contingent behavior to estimate the value of sports fishing in the Lagoon of Venice. Ecol Econ 61(2–3):530–541

Allenby GM, Rossi PE (1998) Marketing models of consumer heterogeneity. J Econom 89(1–2):57–78

Álvarez-Farizo B, Hanley N, Barberán R (2001) The value of leisure time: a contingent rating approach. J Environ Plan Manage 44(5):681–699

Amoako-Tuffour J, Martínez-Espiñeira R (2012) Leisure and the net opportunity cost of travel time in recreation demand analysis: an application to Gros Morne National Park. J Appl Econ 15(1):25–49

Anable J, Gatersleben B (2005) All work and no play? The role of instrumental and affective factors in work and leisure journeys by different travel modes. Transp Res Part A Policy Pract 39(2):163–181

Bartczak A, Lindhjem H, Navrud S, Zandersen M, Żylicz T (2008) Valuing forest recreation on the national level in a transition economy: the case of Poland. For Policy Econ 10(7–8):467–472

Bartczak A, Englin J, Pang A (2012) When are forest visits valued the most? An analysis of the seasonal demand for forest recreation in Poland. Environ Resour Econ 52(2):249–264

Becker GS (1965) A theory of the allocation of time. Econ J 75(299):493–517

Bockstael NE, Strand IE, Hanemann WM (1987) Time and the recreational demand model. Am J Agric Econ 69(2):293–302

Börjesson M, Eliasson J (2014) Experiences from the Swedish value of time study. Transp Res Part A Policy Pract 59:144–158

Bovy PH, Stern E (2012) Route choice: wayfinding in transport networks—wayfinding in transport networks. Springer, Berlin

Broach J, Dill J, Gliebe J (2012) Where do cyclists ride? A route choice model developed with revealed preference GPS data. Transp Res Part A Policy Pract 46(10):1730–1740

Cameron TA (1992a) Combining contingent valuation and travel cost data for the valuation of nonmarket goods. Land Econ 68(3):302–317

Cameron TA (1992b) Nonuser resource values. Am J Agric Econ 74(5):1133–1137

Carson R, Czajkowski M (2014) The discrete choice experiment approach to environmental contingent valuation. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham

Carson RT, Czajkowski M (2019) A new baseline model for estimating willingness to pay from discrete choice models. J Environ Econ Manag 95:57–61

Carson RT, Groves T (2007) Incentive and informational properties of preference questions. Environ Resour Econ 37(1):181–210

Casey JF, Vukina T, Danielson LE (1995) The economic value of hiking: further considerations of opportunity cost of time in recreational demand models. J Agric Appl Econ 27(2):658–668

Cesario FJ (1976) Value of time in recreation benefit studies. Land Econ 52(1):32–41

Champ PA, Boyle KJ, Brown TC (2017) A primer on nonmarket valuation. Springer, Amsterdam

Chavas J-P, Stoll J, Sellar C (1989) On the commodity value of travel time in recreational activities. Appl Econ 21(6):711–722

Chib S, Greenberg E, Winkelmann R (1998) Posterior simulation and Bayes factors in panel count data models. J Econom 86(1):33–54

Clawson M, Knetsch JL (1966) Economics of outdoor recreation. The Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future, Washington

Czajkowski M, Giergiczny M, Kronenberg J, Tryjanowski P (2014) The economic recreational value of a white stork nesting colony: a case of ‘stork village’ in Poland. Tour Manag 40:352–360

Czajkowski M, Ahtiainen H, Artell J, Budziński W, Hasler B, Hasselström L, Meyerhoff J, Nõmmann T, Semeniene D, Söderqvist T, Tuhkanen H, Lankia T, Vanags A, Zandersen M, Żylicz T, Hanley N (2015) Valuing the commons: an international study on the recreational benefits of the Baltic Sea. J Environ Manage 156:209–217

Czajkowski M, Zandersen M, Aslam U, Angelidis I, Becker T, Budziński W, Zagórska K (2018) Recreational value of the baltic sea: a spatially explicit site choice model accounting for environmental conditions. Working Paper 11/2018 (270), Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw, Poland

Davis AF, Moeltner K (2010) Valuing the prevention of an infestation: the threat of the New Zealand Mud Snail in Northern Nevada. Agric Resour Econ Rev 39(1):56–74

DeSerpa AC (1971) A theory of the economics of time. Econ J 81(324):828–846

Egan KJ, Herriges JA, Kling CL, Downing JA (2009) Valuing water quality as a function of water quality measures. Am J Agric Econ 91(1):106–123

Englin J, Cameron TA (1996) Augmenting travel cost models with contingent behavior data. Environ Resour Econ 7(2):133–147

Englin J, Shonkwiler JS (1995) Modeling recreation demand in the presence of unobservable travel costs: toward a travel price model. J Environ Econ Manag 29(3):368–377

Evans AW (1972) On the theory of the valuation and allocation of time. Scott J Polit Econ 19(1):1–17

Feather P, Shaw WD (1999) Estimating the cost of leisure time for recreation demand models. J Environ Econ Manag 38(1):49–65

Ferrini S, Scarpa R (2007) Designs with a priori information for nonmarket valuation with choice experiments: a Monte Carlo study. J Environ Econ Manag 53(3):342–363

Fezzi C, Bateman IJ, Ferrini S (2014) Using revealed preferences to estimate the value of travel time to recreation sites. J Environ Econ Manag 67(1):58–70

Fleming CM, Cook A (2008) The recreational value of Lake McKenzie, Fraser Island: an application of the travel cost method. Tour Manag 29(6):1197–1205

Fletcher JJ, Adamowicz WL, Graham-Tomasi T (1990) The travel cost model of recreation demand: theoretical and empirical issues. Leis Sci 12(1):119–147

Garrod G, Willis KG (1999) Economic valuation of the environment: methods and case studies. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

Gawrońska G, Gawroński K, Dymek D, Sankowski E, Harris B (2018) Economic valuation of high natural value areas in central roztocze. Acta Scientiarum Polonorum. Formatio Circumiectus 17(4):45

Gelman A, Carlin JB, Stern HS, Rubin DB (2003) Bayesian data analysis, 2nd edn. Chapman and Hall/CRC, Boca Raton

Gürlük S, Rehber E (2008) A travel cost study to estimate recreational value for a bird refuge at Lake Manyas, Turkey. J Environ Manag 88(4):1350–1360

Hanemann WM (1984) Welfare evaluations in contingent valuation experiments with discrete responses. Am J Agric Econ 66(3):332–341

Hanley N, Barbier EB (2009) Pricing nature. Cost-benefit analysis and environmental policy. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

Hanley N, Bell D, Alvarez-Farizo B (2003) Valuing the benefits of coastal water quality improvements using contingent and real behaviour. Environ Resour Econ 24(3):273–285

Hausman JA, Leonard GK, McFadden D (1995) A utility-consistent, combined discrete choice and count data model assessing recreational use losses due to natural resource damage. J Public Econ 56(1):1–30

Hellerstein D, Mendelsohn R (1993) A theoretical foundation for count data models. Am J Agric Econ 75(3):604–611

Huber J, Train K (2001) On the similarity of classical and Bayesian estimates of individual mean partworths. Market Lett 12(3):259–269

Huhtala A, Lankia T (2012) Valuation of trips to second homes: Do environmental attributes matter? J Environ Plann Manage 55(6):733–752

Hynes S, Hanley N, O’Donoghue C (2009) Alternative treatments of the cost of time in recreational demand models: an application to whitewater kayaking in Ireland. J Environ Manage 90(2):1014–1021

Jara-Díaz SR, Munizaga MA, Greeven P, Guerra R, Axhausen K (2008) Estimating the value of leisure from a time allocation model. Transp Res Part B Methodol 42(10):946–957

Johnson MB (1966) Travel time and the price of leisure. Econ Inq 4(2):135–145

Johnston RJ, Boyle KJ, Adamowicz W, Bennett J, Brouwer R, Cameron TA, Hanemann WM, Hanley N, Ryan M, Scarpa R, Tourangeau R, Vossler CA (2017) Contemporary guidance for stated preference studies. J Assoc Environ Resour Econ 4(2):319–405

Kulczyk S, Derek M, Woźniak E (2016) How much is the “wonder of nature” worth? The valuation of tourism in the great Masurian lakes using travel cost method. Ekonom Środowisko 4:235–249

Larson DM, Lew DK (2005) Measuring the utility of ancillary travel: revealed preferences in recreation site demand and trips taken. Transp Res Part A Policy Pract 39(2):237–255

Larson DM, Lew DK (2014) The opportunity cost of travel time as a noisy wage fraction. Am J Agric Econ 96(2):420–437

Larson DM, Shaikh SL, Layton D (2004) Revealing preferences for leisure time from stated preference data. Am J Agric Econ 86(2):307–320

Lindhjem H, Navrud S (2009) Asking for individual or household willingness to pay for environmental goods? Environ Resour Econ 43(1):11–29

Lloyd-Smith P, Abbott JK, Adamowicz W, Willard D (2019) Decoupling the value of leisure time from labor market returns in travel cost models. J Assoc Environ Resour Econ 6(2):215–242

Lyons G, Urry J (2005) Travel time use in the information age. Transp Res Part A Policy Pract 39(2):257–276

McConnell KE (1975) Some problems in estimating the demand for outdoor recreation. Am J Agric Econ 57(2):330–334

McFadden D (1976) The revealed preferences of a government bureaucracy: empirical evidence. Bell J Econ 7(1):55–72

McFadden D, Train K (2000) Mixed MNL models for discrete response. J Appl Econom 15(5):447–470

Milakis D, Cervero R, van Wee B, Maat K (2015) Do people consider an acceptable travel time? Evidence from Berkeley, CA. J Transp Geogr 44:76–86

Mokhtarian PL (2005) Travel as a desired end, not just a means. Transp Res Part A Policy Pract 39(2):93–96

Mokhtarian PL, Salomon I (2001) How derived is the demand for travel? Some conceptual and measurement considerations. Transp Res Part A Policy Pract 35(8):695–719

Morris EA, Guerra E (2015) Mood and mode: Does how we travel affect how we feel? Transportation 42(1):25–43

Mouter N, Chorus C (2016) Value of time: a citizen perspective. Transp Res Part A Policy Pract 91:317–329

Neher C, Duffield J, Patterson D (2013) Valuation of national park system visitation: the efficient use of count data models, meta-analysis, and secondary visitor survey data. Environ Manage 52(3):683–698

Ory DT, Mokhtarian PL (2005) When is getting there half the fun? Modeling the liking for travel. Transp Res Part A Policy Pract 39(2):97–123

Ovaskainen V, Neuvonen M, Pouta E (2012) Modelling recreation demand with respondent-reported driving cost and stated cost of travel time: a finnish case. J For Econ 18(4):303–317

Palmquist RB, Phaneuf DJ, Smith VK (2010) Short run constraints and the increasing marginal value of time in recreation. Environ Resour Econ 46(1):19–41

Panasiuk D (2001) Wycena środowiska metodą kosztów podróży w praktyce. Wartość turystyczna Pienińskiego Parku Narodowego. W: Ekonomia a rozwój zrównoważony 2:264–277

Parsons GR (2003) The travel cost model. In: Champ PA, Boyle KJ, Brown TC (eds) A primer on nonmarket valuation. Springer, Netherlands, pp 269–329

Parsons GR (2017) The travel cost model. In: Champ PA, Boyle KJ, Brown TC (eds) A primer on nonmarket valuation. Springer, Netherlands, pp 187–233

Randall A (1994) A difficulty with the travel cost method. Land Econ 70(1):88

Rasouli S, Timmermans H (2014) Activity-based models of travel demand: promises, progress and prospects. Int J Urban Sci 18(1):31–60

Revelt D, Train K (2000) Customer-specific taste parameters and mixed logit: households’ choice of electricity supplier. University of California at Berkeley, Berkeley

Rossi PE, McCulloch RE, Allenby GM (1996) The value of purchase history data in target marketing. Market Sci 15(4):321–340

Salomon I, Mokhtarian PL (1998) What happens when mobility-inclined market segments face accessibility-enhancing policies? Transp Res Part D Transp Environ 3(3):129–140

Sartori D, Catalano G, Genco M, Pancotti C, Sirtori E, Vignetti S, Bo C (2014) Guide to cost-benefit analysis of investment projects. Economic appraisal tool for Cohesion Policy 2014–2020

Shaw D (1988) On-site samples’ regression: problems of non-negative integers, truncation, and endogenous stratification. Journal of Econometrics 37(2):211–223

Shaw WD (1992) Searching for the opportunity cost of an individual’s time. Land Econ 68(1):107

Shrestha RK, Seidl AF, Moraes AS (2002) Value of recreational fishing in the Brazilian Pantanal: a travel cost analysis using count data models. Ecol Econ 42(1–2):289–299

Small KA, Rosen HS (1981) Applied welfare economics with discrete choice models. Econometrica 49(1):105–160

Train KE (2009) Discrete choice methods with simulation, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, New York

Von Haefen RH (2002) A complete characterization of the linear, log-linear, and semi-log incomplete demand system models. J Agric Resour Econ 27(2):281–319

Vossler CA, Doyon M, Rondeau D (2012) Truth in consequentiality: theory and field evidence on discrete choice experiments. Am Econ J Microecon 4(4):145–171

Whitaker B (2015) An unlikely tourist attraction in Poland: storks. The New York Times, 2015-11-19

Wiśniewska A, Budziński W, Czajkowski M (2018) Publicly funded cultural institutions – a comparative economic valuation study. University of Warsaw, Department of Economics working paper no. 22(281)

Wolff H (2014) Value of time: speeding behavior and gasoline prices. J Environ Econ Manag 67(1):71–88

Download references

Acknowledgements

The data used in this study was collected in a project funded by the Polish National Science Centre (Grant N N112 29233)9. We thank the participants of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists’ conference, Toulouse, June 2013 for their helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper. Mikołaj Czajkowski gratefully acknowledges the support of the National Science Centre of Poland (Sonata Bis, 2018/30/E/HS4/00388).

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Department of Economics, University of Warsaw, Długa 44/50, 00-241, Warsaw, Poland

Mikołaj Czajkowski & Marek Giergiczny

Faculty of Economics and Sociology, University of Lodz, P.O.W. 3/5, 90-255, Lodz, Poland

Jakub Kronenberg

Morrison School of Agribusiness, Arizona State University, 7171 E. Sonoran Arroyo Mall, Mesa, AZ, 85212, USA

Jeffrey Englin

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mikołaj Czajkowski .

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License ( http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ ), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Czajkowski, M., Giergiczny, M., Kronenberg, J. et al. The Individual Travel Cost Method with Consumer-Specific Values of Travel Time Savings. Environ Resource Econ 74 , 961–984 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-019-00355-6

Download citation

Accepted : 10 June 2019

Published : 24 June 2019

Issue Date : November 2019

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-019-00355-6

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Opportunity cost of travel time
  • Individual-specific values of travel time savings
  • Travel cost method
  • Discrete choice experiment
  • Integration of valuation methods
  • Recreational birdwatching

JEL Classification

  • Find a journal
  • Publish with us
  • Track your research

U.S. flag

A .gov website belongs to an official government organization in the United States.

A lock ( ) or https:// means you've safely connected to the .gov website. Share sensitive information only on official, secure websites.

  • About Rabies
  • Rabies Prevention and Control
  • Rabies Status: Assessment by Country
  • When to Seek Medical Care for Rabies
  • Global Rabies: What You Should Know
  • Clinical Overview of Rabies
  • Information for Veterinarians
  • Rabies pre- and post-exposure prophylaxis
  • Rabies Symptoms and Specimen Collection
  • Laboratory Information/Specimen Submission
  • Protecting Public Health
  • Show All Home

Rabies Pre-exposure Prophylaxis

  • Pre-exposure vaccination is recommended for persons who work directly with animals that could have rabies
  • Also, those who travel to parts of the world where rabies is common and access to medical care is limited.

Pre-exposure vaccination (PrEV)

Most people in the United States have a low risk of encountering an animal with rabies. However, a small subset of people have a higher level of risk, like those who work directly with animals that could have rabies, or those who travel to parts of the world where rabies is common and access to medical care is limited. These people should receive rabies pre-exposure vaccination (PrEV), a series of rabies vaccine doses given before exposure to the rabies virus.

The Advisory Committee on Immunization Practices (ACIP) develops U.S. recommendations about how and when to use vaccines to prevent disease in the United States, including how to prevent rabies in people. ACIP updated rabies vaccine recommendations in May 2022, which are summarized below:

Updates to the ACIP recommendations to prevent human rabies, 2022

  • A 2-dose PrEV schedule has replaced the 3-dose PrEV schedule to protect people from rabies for up to 3 years. Options for maintaining protection beyond 3 years are also described.
  • Risk categories have been redefined into 5 risk groups.
  • The minimum acceptable laboratory value (antibody titer) used to determine whether rabies vaccine booster doses are needed was revised and standardized.
  • Many people for whom serial titers were recommended every 2 years now require only a one-time titer (and booster if below a certain level) OR a one-time booster.

Clinical guidance for administering PrEV to people with weakened immune systems has been outlined and includes recommendations to confirm that the vaccine was effective.

Risk category

Who this typically* affects

Recommendations

Risk category 1 Highest risk

People who work with live or concentrated rabies virus in laboratories

2 doses, days 0 and 7

  • Check titer every 6 months

Risk category 2

People who frequently do at least one of the following: handle bats, have contact with bats, enter high-density bat environments like caves, or perform animal necropsies

  • Check titer every 2 years

Risk category 3

People who interact with, or are at higher risk to interact, with mammals other than bats that could be rabid, for a period longer than three years after they receive PrEP.

This group includes:

  • Most veterinarians, veterinary technicians, animal control officers, wildlife biologists, rehabilitators, trappers, and spelunkers (cave explorers)
  • Certain travelers to regions outside of the United States where rabies in dogs is commonly found

2 doses, days 0 and 7, plus:

  • Either a one-time titer check after 1 year and up to 3 years following the first 2-dose vaccination
  • 1-dose booster between 3 weeks and 3 years following the first vaccine in the 2-dose vaccination

Risk category 4

Same population as risk category 3, but at a higher risk for ≤ three years after they receive PrEV

Risk category 5 Lowest risk

General U.S. population

* The typical characteristics described may not include the characteristics of all activities that fall within the described risk group.

For detailed information about these recommendations, please refer to the published MMWR .

Rabies is a preventable viral disease of mammals usually transmitted through the bite of an infected animal.

For Everyone

Health care providers, public health.

Risk & Economy

Digital transformation, strategy & operations, press releases.

  • search search
  • News keyboard_arrow_down
  • Content Calendar
  • Climate change
  • Financial crime
  • Public Sector
  • Cyber Security
  • Systems & Software
  • Business Partnering
  • C-suite Communication
  • Financial Reporting
  • Leadership & Management
  • Procurement
  • Real estate

Information

  • Advertise with us
  • Submit Opinion
  • CFO Executive Dialogue Post-Event Report
  • Website Terms of Use
  • Privacy Policy
  • Cookie Policy

Business travel expert reveals how to navigate the cost of going green

Incorporating sustainability into business travel programs has shifted from a luxury to a critical requirement in a world increasingly aware of environmental issues.

But according to the findings of a recent report , the higher costs associated with sustainable travel options are a major obstacle to the widespread adoption of environmentally friendly business travel practices.

Although the initial cost of adopting sustainable measures might seem steep, organisations need to consider the long-term importance of sustainable travel to remain relevant in a competitive economic landscape.

Research indicates that 53 percent of employees would prefer to work for companies that actively support sustainable travel initiatives over those that do not.

In line with National Clean Air Month, this article will outline the most effective strategy to help future leaders manage their eco-friendly travel expenses and build sustainable business travel programmes.

Define the reasons for travel and frequency

The first step is to outline the objectives of business travel. Employees often need to travel for various business purposes, such as attending in-person client meetings, conferences or training sessions.

Nevertheless, excess corporate travel is likely to conflict with sustainability goals. Therefore, it’s crucial businesses pinpoint what constitutes essential travel.

Implementing a system to capture and categorise reason codes for each business trip will help identify trends where travel is unnecessary in favour of virtual alternatives.

In taking a more strategic, purposeful approach to business travel, organisations can reduce unnecessary expenses, minimise their environmental footprint and ensure face-to-face interactions are reserved for situations where they add the most value.

Create a clear travel expense policy

Effective management of business travel expenses also significantly enhances a company’s sustainability profile. However, a key challenge is that one-fifth of expense managers fail to ensure employees adhere to their company’s travel expense policy.

Ensuring that expense policies are communicated clearly and are readily accessible via the company intranet or during dedicated meetings can improve compliance and cost efficiency.

AP The importance of UX in accounts payable: Often overlooked, always essential

Ap the power of customisation in accounting systems, ap 8 key metrics to measure to optimise accounts payable efficiency, banking spend reporting wastes time - it does not have to be this way.

Implementing and utilising robust travel expense management software provides real-time dashboards to monitor expenditures across various departments and projects. This helps businesses analyse trends, set realistic budgets based on past spending, and identify peak seasons which typically incur higher costs.

Organising expenses into foundational categories such as air travel, accommodations, and meals not only streamlines the prediction and management of budgets but also facilitates a more sustainable approach by identifying areas where environmentally friendly options can be integrated.

Encouraging the use of vetted travel vendors and integrating both online and offline booking options ensures safer, more cost-effective travel arrangements. These practices not only optimise expense management but support the implementation of greener travel policies, reducing a company’s carbon footprint and promoting a sustainable business model.

Make policies greener and more sustainable

Policies also serve as a crucial tool to educate travellers about effective methods for reducing the environmental impact of their journeys. Often simply equipping travellers with the necessary tools, information, and expertise allows them to foster more sustainable travel practices. Implementing policies is not costly, yet provides practical, cost-effective strategies for minimising the carbon footprint associated with business travel.

To lower carbon emissions these policies should advocate for choosing trains or electric vehicles over planes, favouring fewer but longer trips and selecting accommodations with genuine sustainability accreditations . Examples to look out for when hospitality and other service providers include the Green Key certificate , the ISO 14001 accreditation and the EU Ecolabel .

To make this an efficient process, travel management companies (TMCs) can help as they have the experience and expertise to build comprehensive and personalised travel policies tailored to empower travellers to make more sustainable choices at the point of booking while minimising costs where possible.

Leverage technology and sustainability-driven partnerships

Implementing the right tools and technology can help quantify the environmental impact of business travel and can assist in evaluating the ROI from an environmental and cost perspective.

Online platforms streamline this process and offer innovative solutions for real-time carbon footprint data tracking and carbon emission projections of future business travel programmes. These platforms also keep a carbon record of all past business travel, helpful in sustainability and CO2 reporting.

By partnering with experts in curating ‘green travel’, businesses can introduce accurate approval mechanisms dependent on CO2 emissions for planned trips and navigate additional costs effectively, not only achieving sustainable ROI but also staying ahead in the race for top talent and a greener, more responsible future.

Partnering with hotels, service providers and airlines that prioritise sustainability practices is an effective way to ensure that business travel is promoting greener travel options. Plus, nurturing these relationships can open doors for better pricing and cost-saving options.

Furthermore, negotiating corporate rates with preferred service providers and utilising reward schemes are effective strategies for reducing costs while promoting sustainability.

Comments are closed.

Subscribe to get your daily business insights

Join a global community of senior cfo leaders, and access the latest analysis and reports, related articles, what's up with starbucks' yo-yoing prices, when life gives you oranges... oh wait, the great oil divide, you don't have to spend money to manage money, can cfos really blame the weather for a drop in profit, ineffective financial planning hits profitability, new research shows, is there a power behind zero-based budgeting, the hidden cost of fear-driven leadership: a £2.2 billion productivity drai....

IMAGES

  1. PPT

    how travel cost method works

  2. PPT

    how travel cost method works

  3. PPT

    how travel cost method works

  4. PPT

    how travel cost method works

  5. PPT

    how travel cost method works

  6. PPT

    how travel cost method works

VIDEO

  1. Travel Cost Method and Hedonic Pricing Method

  2. Travel cost method

  3. 07 Transportation Problem

  4. GROUP 9 : TRAVEL COST METHOD

  5. 08 Transportation Problem

  6. Economic Valuation of Environmental Goods and Services

COMMENTS

  1. Chapter 15: Environmental Valuation: The Travel Cost Method

    taxes). 2 If gas mileage is 25 miles to the gallon—at an assumed average speed of 50 miles per. hour —and if the individual lives 50 miles away from the recreational site, the cost of the ...

  2. Travel Cost Method

    The travel cost method is used to estimate economic use values associated with ecosystems or sites that are used for recreation. The method can be used to estimate the economic benefits or costs resulting from: changes in access costs for a recreational site. elimination of an existing recreational site. addition of a new recreational site.

  3. PDF TRAVEL COST METHOD (TCM)

    TCM is used to value recreational uses of the environment. It is commonly applied in benefit cost analyses (BCA) and in natural resource damage assessments. It is based on „observed behaviour‟, thus is used to estimate use values only. TCM is a demand-based model for use of a recreation site or sites. A site: a river for fishing, a trail ...

  4. Travel cost method

    The Travel Cost Method (TCM) is one of the most frequently used approaches to estimating the use values of recreational sites. The TCM was initially suggested by Hotelling [1] and subsequently developed by Clawson [2] in order to estimate the benefits from recreation at natural sites. The method is based on the premise that the recreational ...

  5. Environmental Valuation: The Travel Cost Method

    The travel cost method estimates the economic value of recreational sites or other concentrated environmental amenities (e.g., wildlife observation) by looking at the full travel costs (time, out of pocket, and any applicable fees) of visiting the sites. In existence since a letter written in 1949 from Harold Hotelling to the director of the ...

  6. Travel cost analysis

    The travel cost method of economic valuation, travel cost analysis, or Clawson method is a revealed preference method of economic valuation used in cost-benefit analysis to calculate the value of something that cannot be obtained through market prices (i.e. national parks, beaches, ecosystems). The aim of the method is to calculate ...

  7. The travel cost method: a valuable tool for organizers ...

    A methodological approach to evaluate the value of EE is the travel cost method (TCM), which is a non-market valuation method in the field of environmental economics that uses travel data to determine what individuals are willing to pay to access a site of interest. ... For those traveling outside of work, the hourly income metric for ...

  8. Valuing the Environment 03: Revealed Preference Travel Cost Method

    This video introduces Revealed Preference evaluation techniques, and discusses the Travel Cost method in detail.

  9. Travel Cost Models

    These often work for a travel cost model. Sites are often aggregated. Some examples are sites defined by hydrologic ... K. E., Giergiczny, M. & Mahieu, P. (2011). Applying the travel cost method to Minorca beaches: Some policy results. In J. Bennett (Ed.), The international handbook on non-market environmental valuation (pp. 60-73). Cheltenham ...

  10. PDF Environmental Valuation: The Travel Cost Method

    How does the travel cost method work? The fundamental idea is that the number of trips a household makes to a recreational site in a given time period is analogous to the number of

  11. Valuation of Ecosystem Services: Travel Cost Method

    This video is a part of Conservation Strategy Fund's collection of environmental economics lessons and was made possible thanks to the support of Jon Mellber...

  12. The Travel Cost Model

    The travel cost model is used to value recreational uses of the environment. For example, it may be used to value the recreation loss associated with a beach closure due to an oil spill or to value the recreation gain associated with improved water quality on a river. The model is commonly applied in benefit-cost analyses and in natural ...

  13. PDF Travel Cost Method

    travel time - Assume Zone 0 = zero travel distance and time - Multiply average travel distance for each zone by standard cost per mile (£0.3 per mile) - Multiply average travel time for each zone by the cost of time (e.g. average hourly rate, £9/hour or £0.15/minute) - Add travel and time cost together

  14. What is the Travel Cost Method?

    This video introduces concept of Travel Cost Method. A.k.a Zonal Travel Cost Method. This method uses actual visitors to find Willingness To Pay (WTP) to val...

  15. PDF Chapter 15. Travel Cost Method of Valuing Environmental Amenities

    There are, however, a number of caveats to bear in mind when using the travel cost method. It assumes that individuals respond to changes in explicit travel costs (e.g. $.35 per mile) as they do to implicit travel costs (time), and also just as they would to changes in admission price (indeed, the three categories are all lumped together).

  16. PDF Travel cost methods

    spend resources (time and money) to travel to the site. The travel activity is a reflection of the use value this service has to people. The travel costs method was first applied in the US in 1959 to value the recreational use of nature. There are basically two different types of travel cost methods; one based on a

  17. Travel-cost method for assessing the monetary value of recreational

    Total travel cost: The increase in total travel costs, TC i, negatively affects the log persontrips' frequency (β ̂ = − 0.006), as expected from the travel-cost method. That means, for each 1 TL increase in total travel cost per person, the expected log count of the persontrips decreases by 0.006 while holding all other variables in the ...

  18. Travel-cost method

    The travel-cost method (TCM) is used for calculating economic values of environmental goods. Unlike the contingent valuation method, TCM can only estimate use value of an environmental good or service. It is mainly applied for determining economic values of sites that are used for recreation, such as national parks. For example, TCM can ...

  19. The travel cost method and the economic value of leisure time

    The travel cost method and the economic value of leisure time. January 1, 2004. Recent estimates of high values for tourist related recreation USA amenity values indicate that allocation of basic water and terrestrial resources to recreation activities should be given precedence over conventional market oriented activities that often degrade or ...

  20. Travel Cost Method

    The travel cost method involves collecting data on the costs incurred by each individual in travelling to the recreational site or amenity. This 'price' paid by visitors is unique to each individual, and is calculated by summing the travel costs from each individuals original location to the amenity. ... This work is licensed under a ...

  21. PDF Liam Carr and Robert Mendelsohn Valuing Coral Reefs: A Travel Cost

    The travel cost method is a well-known and developed method-ology for measuring the economic values of outdoor recreation benefits (16-18). Although the travel cost method may have its difficulties (19, 20), the method has the advantage that it infers values from people's behavior. It is the very fact that people are

  22. Disney Genie+ is changing: What guests should know

    The ride reservation system is getting a new name and new perks to help Walt Disney World guests plan their trips further in advance.

  23. 2023-24 Working from home deductions

    incur extra running costs related to working from home. be doing work-related tasks from home, not just minor tasks (like checking emails) have records to prove your expenses. Fixed Rate Method. You can claim a fixed rate of 67 cents for each hour you work from home. This rate covers: energy costs - for heating, cooling and lighting

  24. How to upgrade to first class without spending a ton of money

    If you notice low demand for your desired seat as the travel date approaches, see if you can scoop up an upgrade at a discounted cash rate. While the price will vary, it never hurts to check. Look at your upcoming flight reservations every now to see what the airline is listing as the cost to upgrade your seat with cash.

  25. When Is the Best Time to Book a Flight for Travel in 2024?

    Do you want to know the best time to book a flight for your next trip? Whether you are planning to travel domestically, internationally, or during the summer, we have the tips you need to save ...

  26. The Individual Travel Cost Method with Consumer-Specific Values of

    The treatment of the opportunity cost of travel time in travel cost models has been an area of research interest for many decades. Our analysis develops a methodology to combine the travel distance and travel time data with respondent-specific estimates of the value of travel time savings (VTTS). The individual VTTS are elicited with the use of discrete choice stated preference methods. The ...

  27. Rabies Pre-exposure Prophylaxis

    Pre-exposure vaccination (PrEV) Most people in the United States have a low risk of encountering an animal with rabies. However, a small subset of people have a higher level of risk, like those who work directly with animals that could have rabies, or those who travel to parts of the world where rabies is common and access to medical care is limited.

  28. Travel cost method

    An overview of the travel cost method

  29. Moving to the UK 2024: Everything You Need to Know ...

    Skilled Worker visa costs from GBP 719 to GBP 1,500. Plus, you will need to pay the healthcare surcharge of around GBP 1,035 for each year you're in the UK. Graduate Work visa. With a UK Graduate Work visa, you can work flexibly, switch jobs, and develop your career for two years after completing a course in the UK. Requirements. you're in ...

  30. Navigating Costs in Sustainable Business Travel: Expert Insights

    Research indicates that 53 percent of employees would prefer to work for companies that actively support sustainable travel initiatives over those that do not.. In line with National Clean Air Month, this article will outline the most effective strategy to help future leaders manage their eco-friendly travel expenses and build sustainable business travel programmes.